Vaz de Castro, Afonso (2022): Risk Aversion and Recessive Impacts of Austerity.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_111875.pdf Download (947kB) | Preview |
Abstract
This paper aims to contribute for the vast literature on the impact of country-specific characteristics on fiscal multipliers. We argue that countries have relevant differences in risk attitudes, and that those differences are economically significant in determining output responses to fiscal consolidation programs. We start with an empirical analysis, estimating the coefficient of relative risk aversion for nine European economies, finding relevant heterogeneity across countries. Using the coefficients found, we calibrate an incomplete markets overlapping generations model and study the impacts of an unanticipated fiscal consolidation shock. We find a positive relationship between fiscal multipliers and risk aversion when there is a spending-based consolidation, showing that recessive impacts from austerity are stronger the larger the degree of risk aversion. The underlying mechanism depends on the effect of risk aversion on precautionary savings behavior and so on the share of constrained agents. Larger risk aversion induces more precautionary savings, thus shrinking the share of constrained agents. Credit-constrained agents have a less responsive labor supply with respect to spending-based fiscal consolidation shocks.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Risk Aversion and Recessive Impacts of Austerity |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Fiscal Multipliers, Fiscal Consolidation, Relative Risk Aversion |
Subjects: | E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy > E21 - Consumption ; Saving ; Wealth E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E6 - Macroeconomic Policy, Macroeconomic Aspects of Public Finance, and General Outlook > E62 - Fiscal Policy H - Public Economics > H3 - Fiscal Policies and Behavior of Economic Agents > H31 - Household H - Public Economics > H6 - National Budget, Deficit, and Debt > H63 - Debt ; Debt Management ; Sovereign Debt I - Health, Education, and Welfare > I3 - Welfare, Well-Being, and Poverty > I31 - General Welfare, Well-Being |
Item ID: | 111875 |
Depositing User: | Mr. Afonso Vaz de Castro |
Date Deposited: | 07 Mar 2022 08:27 |
Last Modified: | 07 Mar 2022 08:27 |
References: | [1] Alesina, A., O. Barbiero, C. Favero, F. Giavazzi, and M. Paradisi (2017). The effects of fiscal consolidations: Theory and evidence. (23385). [2] Auerbach, A. J. and Y. Gorodnichenko (2012, May). Measuring the output responses to fiscal policy. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4(2), 1–27. [3] Basso, H. S. and O. Rachedi (2018, November). The young, the old, and the government: demographics and fiscal multipliers. Working Papers 1837, Banco de España. [4]Baum, M. A., M. M. Poplawski-Ribeiro, and A. Weber (2012). Fiscal Multipliers and the State of the Economy. International Monetary Fund. [5]Benabou, R. (2002). Tax and education policy in a heterogeneous agent economy: What levels of redistribution maximize growth and efficiency? Econometrica 70, 481–517. [6] Benjamin, D. J., O. Heffetz, M. S. Kimball, and A. Rees-Jones (2012, May). What do you think would make you happier? what do you think you would choose? American Economic Review 102(5), 2083–2110. [7] Bernardino, T. (2019). Asset liquidity and fiscal consolidation programs. [8] Bernoulli, D. (1954). Exposition of a new theory on the measurement of risk. Econometrica 22(1), 23–36. [9] Blanchard, O. J. and D. Leigh (2013, May). Growth forecast errors and fiscal multipliers. American Economic Review 103(3), 117–20. [10] Blanchard, O. J. and L. H. Summers (2020). 20-2 automatic stabilizers in a low-rate environment. [11] Brinca, P. (2020). Modern macroeconomics and heterogeneity. Notas económicas (51), 7–20. [12] Brinca, P., M. Faria-e Castro, M. Homem Ferreira, and H. Holter (2019). The nonlinear effects of fiscal policy. FRB St. Louis Working Paper (2019-15). [13] Brinca, P., M. H. Ferreira, F. Franco, H. A. Holter, and L. Malafry (2021). Fiscal consolidation programs and income inequality. International Economic Review 62(1), 405–460. [14] Brinca, P., B. Freitas, and M. Mano (2020). Labor share heterogeneity and fiscal consolidation programs. CeBER Working Papers, 1–28. [15] Brinca, P., H. A. Holter, P. Krusell, and L. Malafry (2016). Fiscal multipliers in the 21st century. Journal of Monetary Economics 77, 53–69. [16] Brinca, P., J. Oliveira, and J. Duarte (2019). Investment-specific technological change, taxation and inequality in the us. [17] Chetty, R. (2006). A new method of estimating risk aversion. American Economic Review 96(5), 1821–1834. [18] Diener, E. and E. M. Suh (2003). 22-national differences in subjective well-being. Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology. [19] Gandelman, N. and R. Hernández-Murillo (2015). Risk aversion at the country level. [20] Grancini, S. (2021). Risk aversion and fiscal consolidation programs. [21] Guner, N., M. Lopez-Daneri, and G. Ventura (2014). Heterogeneity and government revenues: Higher taxes at the top? Working Paper. [22] Hansen, L. P. and K. J. Singleton (1983). Stochastic consumption, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of asset returns. Journal of Political Economy 91(2), 249–265. [23] Heathcote, J., K. Storesletten, and G. L. Violante (2017). Optimal tax progressivity: An analytical framework. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 132(4), 1693–1754. [24] Holter, H., D. Krueger, and S. Stepanchuk (2017). How do tax progressivity and household heterogeneity affect laffer curves. Working paper. [25] Ilzetzki, E., E. G. Mendoza, and C. A. Vegh (2013). How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers? Journal of Monetary Economics 60(2), 239–254. [26] Kaplan, G. and G. L. Violante (2014). A model of the consumption response to fiscal stimulus payments. Econometrica 82(4), 1199–1239. [27] Kilponen, J., M. Pisani, S. Schmidt, V. Corbo, T. Hledik, J. Hollmayr, S. Hurtado, P. Júlio, D. Kulikov, M. Lemoine, et al. (2015). Comparing fiscal multipliers across models and countries in europe. [28] Layard, R., G. Mayraz, and S. Nickell (2008). The marginal utility of income. Journal of Public Economics 92(8), 1846–1857. Special Issue: Happiness and Public Economics. [29] Malafry, L. and P. Brinca (2022). Climate policy in an unequal world: Assessing the cost of risk on vulnerable households. Ecological Economics 194, 107309. [30] Mankiw, N. G. and M. D. Shapiro (1984, July). Risk and return: Consumption versus market beta. Working Paper 1399, National Bureau of Economic Research. [31] McKay, A. and R. Reis (2021). Optimal automatic stabilizers. The Review of Economic Studies 88(5), 2375–2406. [32] Neely, C., A. Roy, and C. Whiteman (1995, 02). Identification failure in the intertemporal consumption capm. [33] Oh, H. and R. Reis (2012). Targeted transfers and the fiscal response to the great recession. Journal of Monetary Economics 59, S50–S64. [34] Reichling, F. and C. Whalen (2012). Review of estimates of the frisch elasticity of labor supply. Working Paper Congressional Budget Office. [35] Trabandt, M. and H. Uhlig (2012). How do laffer curves differ across countries? National Bureau of Economic Research. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/111875 |