Tarasov, Alexander (2008): Per Capita Income, Market Access Costs, and Trade Volumes.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_19989.pdf Download (316kB) | Preview |
Abstract
There is strong empirical evidence that countries with lower per capita income tend to have smaller trade volumes even after controlling for aggregate income. Furthermore, poorer countries do not just trade less, but have a lower number of trading partners. In this paper, I construct and estimate a general equilibrium model of trade that captures both these features of the trade data. There are two novelties in the paper. First, I introduce an association between market access costs and countries' development levels, which can account for the effect of per capita income on trade volumes and explain many zeros in bilateral trade flows. Secondly, I develop an estimation procedure, which allows me to estimate both variable and fixed costs of trade. I find that given the estimated parameters, the model performs well in matching the data. In particular, the predicted trade elasticity with respect to income per capita is close to that in the data.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Per Capita Income, Market Access Costs, and Trade Volumes |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | export zeros; fixed costs of trade; country extensive margin. |
Subjects: | F - International Economics > F1 - Trade > F11 - Neoclassical Models of Trade |
Item ID: | 19989 |
Depositing User: | Alexander Tarasov |
Date Deposited: | 14 Jan 2010 16:05 |
Last Modified: | 10 Oct 2019 12:02 |
References: | Arkolakis, C. (2008), "Market Penetration Costs and the New Consumers Margin in International Trade," NBER WP 14214. Bernard, A. B., Eaton, J., Jensen, J. B. and Kortum, S. (2003), "Plants and Productivity in International Trade," American Economic Review, 93(4), 1268-1290. Bernard, A. B., Redding, S. and Schott, P. K. (2007), "Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms," Review of Economic Studies, 74(1), 31-66. Broda, C. and Weinstein, D. E. (2006), "Globalization and the Gains from Variety," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), 541-585. Centre d'Etudes Prospectives et d'Informations Internationales, CEPII (2005), The CEPII Databases-Distances, http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/distances.htm Chaney, T. (2008), "Distorted gravity: the Intensive and Extensive Margins of International Trade," American Economic Review, 98(4), 1707-1721. Chen, M., Otsuki, T. and Wilson, J. (2006), "Do Standards Matter for Export Success?" World Bank Policy Research Working Papers. No. 3809. Doing Business (2006), "Doing Business 2006," The World Bank Group, http://www.doingbusiness.org Eaton, J. and Kortum, S. (2002), "Technology, Geography, and Trade." Econometrica, 70(5), 1741-79. Eaton, J., Kortum, S. and Kramarz F. (2008), "An Anatomy of International Trade: Evidence from French Firms," University of Minnesota, mimeograph. Feenstra, R., Lipsey, R. E., Deng, H., Ma, A. C. and Mo, H. (2005), "World Trade Flows: 1962-2000," NBER Working Paper, No. 11040. Fieler, A. C. (2009), "Non-Homotheticity and Bilateral Trade: Evidence and a Quantitative Explanation," working paper. Flam, H. and Helpman, E. (1987), "Vertical Product Differentiation and North-South Trade," American Economic Review, 77, 810-822. Ghironi, F. and Melitz, M. (2005), "International Trade and Macroeconomic Dynamics with Heterogeneous Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(3), 865-915. Helpman, E., Melitz, M. and Rubinstein, Y. (2008), "Estimating Trade Flows: Trading Partners and Trading Volumes," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 441-487. Hummels, D. and Klenow, P. J. (2002), "The Variety and Quality of a Nation's Trade," NBER WP 8712. Hunter, L. C. (1991), "The Contribution of Nonhomothetic Preferences to Trade," Journal of International Economics, 30, 345-58. Johnson, R. C. (2007), "Trade and Prices with Heterogeneous Firms," UC Berkeley, mimeograph. Markusen, J. (1986), "Explaining the Volume of Trade: An Eclectic Approach," American Economic Review, 76, 1002-1011. Matsuyama, K. (2000), "A Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods under Nonhomothetic Preferences: Demand Complementarities, Income Distribution, and North-South Trade," Journal of Political Economy, 108, 1093-1120. Melitz, M. (2003), "The impact of trade on intraindustry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity," Econometrica, 71(6), 1695-1725. Mersha, T. (1997), "TQM Implementation in LDCs: Driving and Restraining Forces," International Journal of Operations and Production Management, 17(2), 164-183. Mitra, D. and Trindade, V. (2005), "Inequality and Trade," Canadian Journal of Economics, 38, 1253-1271. Nordas, H., Pinali, E. and Gross, MG. (2006), "Logistics and Time as a Trade Barrier," OECD Trade Policy Working Papers, No 35. Potoski, M. and Prakash, A. (2009), "Information Asymmetries as Trade Barriers: ISO 9000 Increases International Commerce," Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 28(2), 221-238. Stokey, N. (1991), "The Volume and Composition of Trade between Rich and Poor Countries," Review of Economic Studies, 58, 63-80. United Nation Statistics Division (2007), "Industrial Statistics Database," 2007, http://comtrade.un.org/db/default.aspx Waugh, M. (2009), "International Trade and Income Differences," University of Iowa, mimeograph. World Bank (2007), "World Development Indicators," 2007. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/19989 |