Stark, Oded and Fan, Simon C. (2010): "A Theory of Migration as a Response to Occupational Stigma". Forthcoming in: International Economic Review
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_21688.pdf Download (323kB) | Preview |
Abstract
A theory is developed of labor migration that is prompted by a desire to avoid "social humiliation." In a general equilibrium framework it is shown that as long as migration can reduce humiliation sufficiently, migration will occur even between two identical economies. Migration increases the number of individuals who choose to perform degrading jobs and consequently, migration lowers the price of the good produced in the sector that is associated with low social status. Moreover, the greater an individual's aversion to performing degrading jobs, the more likely it is that he will experience a welfare gain when the economy opens up.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | "A Theory of Migration as a Response to Occupational Stigma" |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Migration; Social distance; Occupational status; Social exposure gains; General equilibrium |
Subjects: | F - International Economics > F2 - International Factor Movements and International Business > F22 - International Migration J - Labor and Demographic Economics > J6 - Mobility, Unemployment, Vacancies, and Immigrant Workers > J61 - Geographic Labor Mobility ; Immigrant Workers R - Urban, Rural, Regional, Real Estate, and Transportation Economics > R2 - Household Analysis > R23 - Regional Migration ; Regional Labor Markets ; Population ; Neighborhood Characteristics |
Item ID: | 21688 |
Depositing User: | Oded Stark |
Date Deposited: | 12 Apr 2010 14:01 |
Last Modified: | 06 Oct 2019 08:59 |
References: | Agarwal, B. and A. Vercelli, Psychology, Rationality and Economic Behavior (Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan, 2005). Akerlof, G. A., "A Theory of Social Custom, of Which Unemployment May be One Consequence," Quarterly Journal of Economics 94 (1980), 749-775. Akerlof, G. A., "Social Distance and Social Decisions," Econometrica 65 (1997), 1005-1027. Akerlof, G. A., "The Missing Motivation in Macroeconomics," American Economic Review 97 (2007), 5-36. Akerlof, G. A. and R. E. Kranton, "Economics and Identity," Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (2000), 715-753. Alexander, L. G., New Concept English (London: Longman, 1967). Becker, G. S., K. M. Murphy, and I. Werning, "The Equilibrium Distribution of Income and the Market for Status," Journal of Political Economy 113 (2005), 282-310. Bender, K. A., "The Central Government-Private Sector Wage Differential," Journal of Economic Surveys 12 (1998), 177-220. Butler, R. J. and J. D. Worrall, "Wage and Injury Response to Shifts in Workplace Liability," Industrial and Labor Relations Review 61 (2008), 181-200. Cole, H. L., G. J. Mailath, and A. Postlewaite, "Social Norms, Savings Behavior, and Growth," Journal of Political Economy 100 (1992), 1092-1125. Del Bono, E. and A. Weber, "Do Wages Compensate for Anticipated Working Time Restrictions? Evidence from Seasonal Employment in Austria," Journal of Labor Economics 26 (2008), 181-221. Diaz-Serrano, L., J. Hartog, and H. Nielsen, "Compensating Wage Differentials for Schooling Risk in Denmark," Scandinavian Journal of Economics 110 (2008), 711-731. Edlund, L., J. Engelberg, and C. A. Parsons, "The Wages of Sin," mimeo, Columbia University, 2009. Ehrenberg, R. G. and R. S. Smith, Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy. (Boston, MA: Pearson / Addison Wesley, 2009). Fershtman, C. and Y. Weiss, "Social Status, Culture and Economic Performance," Economic Journal 103 (1993), 946-959. Gertler, P., M. Shah and S. M. Bertozzi, "Risky Business: The Market for Unprotected Commercial Sex," Journal of Political Economy 113 (2005), 518-550. Gaillard, J. and A. M. Gaillard, "Introduction: The International Mobility of Brains: Exodus or Circulation?" Science, Technology and Society 2 (1997), 195-228. Nam, C. B. and M. G. Powers, The Socioeconomic Approach to Status Measurement: with a Guide to Occupational and Socioeconomic Status Scores (Houston, TX: Cap and Gown Press, 1983). Rosen, S., "The Theory of Equalizing Differences," in O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds., Handbook of Labor Economics, (New York: Elsevier Publishers, Vol. 1, 1986), 641-692. Rosenzweig, M. R. and O. Stark, "Consumption Smoothing, Migration and Marriage: Evidence from Rural India," Journal of Political Economy 97 (1989), 905-926. Smith, A., An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Reprint, Edited by E. Cannan, (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1776). Stark, O. and C. S. Fan, "The Analytics of Seasonal Migration," Economics Letters 94 (2007), 304-312. Stark, O., C. Helmenstein, and Y. Yegorov, "Migrants' Savings, Purchasing Power Parity, and the Optimal Duration of Migration," International Tax and Public Finance 4 (1997), 307-324. Stark, O. and J. E. Taylor, "Migration Incentives, Migration Types: The Role of Relative Deprivation," The Economic Journal 101 (1991), 1163-1178. Stark, O., M. Micevska, and J. Mycielski, "Relative Poverty as a Determinant of Migration: Evidence from Poland," Economics Letters 103 (2009), 119-122. Stark, O. and Y. Q. Wang, "Towards a Theory of Self-Segregation as a Response to Relative Deprivation: Steady-State Outcomes and Social Welfare," in L. Bruni and P. L. Porta, eds., Economics and Happiness: Framing the Analysis (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007), 223-242. Treiman, D. J., Occupational Prestige in Comparative Perspective (New York: Academic Press, 1977). Weiss, Y. and C. Fershtman, "Social Status and Economic Performance: A Survey," European Economic Review 42 (1998), 801-820. Zweig, D., S.-F. Chung, and D. Han, "Redefining the Brain Drain: China's Diaspora Option," Science, Technology and Society 13 (2008), 1-33. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/21688 |
Available Versions of this Item
- "A Theory of Migration as a Response to Occupational Stigma". (deposited 12 Apr 2010 14:01) [Currently Displayed]