Schwab, Christian and Tang, Hin-Yue Benny (2011): Die Steuerungswirkungen unterschiedlicher Prozesskostenregelungen: Ein Überblick zum Stand von Theorie und Empirie.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_32746.pdf Download (264kB) | Preview |
Abstract
The so-called English Rule in § 91 ZPO has a longstanding tradition in German civil litigation. Although this “loser pays”- fee shifting can raise severe problems like sharply reducing access to the courts for parties of moderate means, the adaption of alternative cost regimes like the U.S.-style American Rule where no fee shifting occurs has never been seriously considered. What is more, the German debate seems to completely ignore the findings of the extensive law and economics literature on fee shifting. This paper addresses this task and surveys the theoretical and empirical literature on the effects of alternative fee shifting systems on a variety of decisions arising during the litigation process. In detail, we put some arguments supporting German-style fee shifting to the test: Does the German system really discourage low-probability-of-prevailing lawsuits that would be brought under the American Rule? Does it encourage the settlement of litigation? And does the German solution lead to lower costs of the legal system compared to alternative fee regimes? The findings indicate that the influence of different fee shifting rules on parties´ decision-making behavior is to a large extent ambiguous. Policy makers should be aware of these problems.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Die Steuerungswirkungen unterschiedlicher Prozesskostenregelungen: Ein Überblick zum Stand von Theorie und Empirie |
English Title: | The economic effects of alternative fee shifting rules: A review of the theoretical and empirical literature |
Language: | German |
Keywords: | Civil Litigation; Fee Shifting; English Rule; American Rule |
Subjects: | K - Law and Economics > K4 - Legal Procedure, the Legal System, and Illegal Behavior > K40 - General K - Law and Economics > K4 - Legal Procedure, the Legal System, and Illegal Behavior > K41 - Litigation Process |
Item ID: | 32746 |
Depositing User: | Christian Schwab |
Date Deposited: | 12 Aug 2011 01:23 |
Last Modified: | 14 Oct 2019 16:25 |
References: | Adams, M. (2002), Ökonomische Theorie des Rechts – Konzepte und Anwendungen, Frankfurt am Main. Anderson, D.A. und T.D. Rowe (1995), “Empirical Evidence on Settlement Devices: Does Rule 68 Encourage Settlement?”, Chicago-Kent Law Review, Vol. 71, S. 519–545. Ann, C. (2010), „Klägerfreundlichkeit im US-Zivilprozess – Gebotene Hilfe für den „kleinen Mann“ oder ungebremster Individualismus zu Lasten anderer?“ in: M. Gloe und V. Reinhardt (Hrsg.), Politikwissenschaft und Politische Bildung, Wiesbaden, S. 156-166. Baetge, D. (2009), „Erfolgshonorare wirtschaftlich betrachtet - Eine ökonomische Analyse der Entscheidung des Bundesverfassungsgerichts über die Zulässigkeit anwaltlicher Erfolgshonorare“, Rabels Zeitschrift für ausländisches und internationales Privatrecht, Vol. 73, S. 669-682. Banks, J.S. und J. Sobel (1987), “Equilibrium Selection in Signaling Games”, Econometrica, Vol. 55, S. 647-661. Baumgärtel, G. (1976), Gleicher Zugang zum Recht für alle - Ein Grundproblem des Rechtsschutzes, Köln. Baye, M.R., D. Kovenock und C.G. de Vries (2005), “Comparative Analysis of Litigation Systems: An Auction-Theoretic Approach”, Economic Journal, Vol. 115, S. 583-601. Bebchuk, L.A. (1984), “Litigation and Settlement under Imperfect Information”, Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 15, S. 404-415. Bebchuk, L.A. und H.F. Chang (1996), “An Analysis of Fee Shifting Based on the Margin of Victory: On Frivolous Suits, Meritorious Suits, and the Role of Rule 11”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 25, S. 371-403. Bokelmann, E. (1973), „‘Rechtswegsperre‘ durch Prozeßkosten“, Zeitschrift für Rechtspolitik, Nr. 7, S. 164-171. Bone, R.G. (2008), “To Encourage Settlement: Rule 68, Offers of Judgment, and the History of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure”, Northwestern University Law Review, Vol. 102, S. 1561-1622. Bork, R., T. Eger und H.-B. Schäfer (Hrsg.) (2009), Ökonomische Analyse des Verfahrensrechts, Tübingen. Braeutigam, R., B. Owen und J. Panzar (1984), “An Economic Analysis of Alternative Fee Shifting Systems”, Law and Contemporary Problems, Vol. 47, S. 173-185. Breyer, M. (2006), Kostenorientierte Steuerung des Zivilprozesses – Das deutsche, englische und amerikanische Prozesskostensystem im Vergleich, Tübingen. Bult, T.R. (2007), “Practical Use and Risky Consequences of Rule 68 Offers of Judgment”, Litigation, Vol. 33, S. 26-30. Chen, K.P. und J.S. Wang (2007), “Fee-Shifting Rules in Litigation with Contingency Fees”, Journal of Law, Economics and Organisation, Vol. 23, S. 519-546. Cheung, R. (1988), “A Bargaining Model of Pretrial Negotiation”, Working Paper No. 49, John M. Olin Program in Law and Economics, Stanford Law School. Cho, I.K. und D.M. Kreps (1987), “Signaling Games and Stable Equilibria”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 102, S. 179-221. Chopard, B., T. Cortade und E. Langlais (2010), “Trial and Settlement Negotiations between Asymmetrically Skilled Parties”, International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 30, S. 18-27. Chung, T.Y. (1996), “Settlement of Litigation under Rule 68: An Economic Analysis”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 25, S. 261. Cooter, R.D., S. Marks und R. Mnookin (1982), “Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: A Testable Model of Strategic Behavior”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 11, S. 225-251. Cooter, R.D. und D.L. Rubinfeld (1989), “Economic Analysis of Legal Disputes and Their Resolution”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 27, S. 1067-1097. Coursey, D.L. und L.R. Stanley (1988), “Pretrial Bargaining Behavior within the Shadow of the Law: Theory and Experimental Evidence”, International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 8, S. 161-179. Däubler, W. (1969), “Bürger ohne Rechtsschutz? Kostenrisiko und Grundgesetz“, BetriebsBerater, Heft 13, S. 545-551. Daughety, A.F. (2000), “Settlement”, in: Bouckaert, B. und G. DeGeest (Hrsg.), Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Cheltenham, Band 7, S. 95-158. Daughety, A.F. und J.F. Reinganum (1994), “Settlement Negotiations with Two-Sided Asymmetric Information: Model Duality, Information Distribution, and Efficiency”, International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 14, S. 283-298. Daughety, A.F. und J.F. Reinganum (2005), “Economic Theories of Settlement Bargaining”, Annual Review of Law and Social Sciences, Vol. 1, S. 35-59. Daughety, A.F. und J.F. Reinganum (1993), “Endogenous Sequencing in Models of Settlement and Litigation”, Journal of Law, Economics and Organisation, Vol. 9, S. 314-348. Dethloff, N. (2000), „Verträge zur Prozessfinanzierung gegen Erfolgsbeteiligung“, Neue Juristische Wochenzeitschrift, 53. Jg., S. 2225-2230. Di Pietro, S. und T.W. Carns (1996), “Alaska's English Rule: Attorney's Fee Shifting in Civil Cases”, Alaska Law Review, Vol. 13, S. 33-93. Di Pietro, S., T.W. Carns und P. Kelley (1995), “Alaska's English Rule: Attorney's Fee Shifting in Civil Cases”, http://www.ajc.state.ak.us/reports/atyfee.pdf (zuletzt abgerufen am 12.03 2011). Eisenberg, T. und S. Schwab (1987), “The Reality of Constitutional Tort Litigation”, Cornell Law Review, Vol. 72, S. 641-695. Farmer, A. und P. Pecorino (1994), “Pretrial Negotiations with Asymmetric Information on Risk Preferences”, International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 14, S. 273-281. Fechner, E. (1969), „Kostenrisiko und Rechtswegsperre – Steht der Rechtsweg offen?“, Juristenzeitung, 24. Jg., S. 349-354. Fiss, O.M. (1984), “Against Settlement”, Yale Law Journal, Vol. 93, S. 1073-1090. Fournier, G.M. und T.W. Zuehlke (1989), “Litigation and Settlement: An Empirical Approach”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 71, S. 189-195. Galanter, M. und M. Cahill (1994), “Most Cases Settle: Judicial Promotion and Regulation of Settlements”, Stanford Law Review, Vol. 46, S. 1339-1391. Gepp, R.C. (1986), “Offers of Judgment in Civil Rights Actions: Analysis and Strategy”, Labor Law Journal, Vol. 37, S. 187-192. Gong, J. und R.P. McAfee (2000), “Pretrial Negotiation, Litigation, and Procedural Rules”, Economic Inquiry, Vol. 38, S. 218-238. Gould, J.P. (1973), “The Economics of Legal Conflicts”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 2, S. 279-300. Gravelle, H.S.E. (1993), “The Efficiency Implications of Cost-Shifting Rules”, International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 13, S. 3-18. Grunsky, W. (1976), Empfehlen sich im Interesse einer effektiven Rechtsverwirklichung für alle Bürger Änderungen des Systems des Kosten- und Gebührenrechts? - Gutachten A für den einundfünfzigsten Deutschen Juristentag, München. Guthrie, C. (2000), “Framing Frivolous Litigation: A Psychological Theory”, The University of Chicago Law Review, Vol. 67, S. 163-216. Hause, J.C. (1989), “Indemnity, Settlement, and Litigation, or I'll Be Suing You”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 18, S. 157-179. Hay, B. und K. Spier (1997), “Litigation and Settlement”, Discussion Paper No. 218, John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business, Harvard Law School. Hicks, G.A. (1989), “Statutory Damage Caps Are an Incomplete Reform: A Proposal for Attorney Fee Shifting in Tort Actions”, Los Angeles Law Review, Vol. 49, S. 763-801. Hughes, J.W. und E.A. Snyder (1995), “Litigation and Settlement under the English and American Rules: Theory and Evidence”, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 38, S. 225-250. Hyde, C.E. und P.L. Williams (2002), “Necessary Costs and Expenditure Incentives under the English Rule”, International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 22, S. 133-152. Hylton, K.N. (1993), “Litigation Cost Allocation Rules and Compliance with the Negligence Standard”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 22, S. 457-476. Hylton, K.N. (1995), “Fee Shifting and Predictability of Law”, Chicago-Kent Law Review, Vol. 71, S. 427-456. Katz, A.W. (1987), “Measuring the Demand for Litigation: Is the English Rule Really Cheaper?”, Journal of Law, Economics and Organisation, Vol. 3, S. 143-176. Katz, A.W. (2000), “Indemnity of Legal Fees”, in: B. Bouckaert und G. DeGeest (Hrsg.), Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Cheltenham, Band 7, S. 63-94. Korobkin, R. und C. Guthrie (1994), “Psychological Barriers to Litigation Settlement: An Experimental Approach”, Michigan Law Review, Vol. 93, S. 107-192. Krent, H.J. (1993), “Explaining One-Way Fee Shifting”, Vanderbilt Law Review, Vol. 79, S. 2039-2089. Kritzer, H.M. (1984), “Fee Arrangements and Fee Shifting: Lesson from the Experience in Ontario”, Law and Contemporary Problems, Vol. 47, S. 125-138. Landes, W.M. (1971), “An Economic Analysis of the Courts”, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 14, S. 61-107. Leipold, D. und A. Zuckerman (1998), Vereinfachung und Beschleunigung des Rechtsschutzes durch summarische Verfahren, Köln. Leubsdorf, J. (1984), “Toward a History of the American Rule on Attorney Fee Recovery”, Law and Contemporary Problems, Vol. 47, S. 9-36. Lewis, H.S. und T.A. Eaton (2006), “Of Offers Not (Frequently) Made and (Rarely) Accepted: The Mystery of Federal Rule 68”, Mercer Law Review, Vol. 57, S. 723-741. Main, B.G. und A. Park (2002), “The Impact of Defendant Offers into Court on Negotiation in the Shadow of the Law: Experimental Evidence”, International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 22, S. 177-192. Miller, G.P. (1986), “An Economic Analysis of Rule 68”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 15, S. 93-125. Mnookin, R.H. (1993), “Why Negotiations Fail: An Exploration of Barriers to the Resolution of Conflict”, Ohio State Journal on Dispute Resolution, Vol. 8, S. 235-249. Olson, S.M. (1995), “How Much Access to Justice From State ‘Equal Access to Justice Acts’?”, Chicago-Kent Law Review, Vol. 71, S. 547-582. Osborne, E. (1999), “Who Should Be Worried About Asymmetric Information in Litigation?”, International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 19, S. 399-409. Pawlowski, H.M. (1975), “Zur Funktion der Prozeßkosten“, Juristenzeitung, Vol. 30, S. 197-202. Percival, R.V. und G.P. Miller (1984), “The Role of Attorney Fee Shifting in Public Interest Litigation”, Law and Contemporary Problems, Vol. 47, S. 233-247. Pfennigstorf, W. (1984), “The European Experience with Attorney Fee Shifting”, Law and Contemporary Problems, Vol. 47, S. 37-124. P'ng, I. (1983), “Strategic Behavior in Suit, Settlement, and Trial”, Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 14, S. 539-550. Polinsky, A.M. und D.L. Rubinfeld (1988), “The Welfare Implications of Costly Litigation for the Level of Liability”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 17, S. 151-164. Polinsky, A.M. und D.L. Rubinfeld (1998), “Does the English Rule Discourage Low-Probability-of-Prevailing Plaintiffs?”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 27, S. 519-535. Posner, R.A. (1973), “An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 2, S. 399-458. Priest, G.L. (1982), “Regulating the Content and Volume of Litigation”, Supreme Court Economic Review, Vol. 1, S. 163-184. Priest, G.L. und B. Klein (1984), “The Selection of Disputes for Litigation”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 13, S. 1-55. Reinganum, J. und L.L. Wilde (1986), “Settlement, Litigation, and the Allocation of Litigation Costs”, RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 17, S. 557-566. Riehl, J. (2003), Prozesskosten und die Inanspruchnahme der Rechtspflege: Eine ökonomische Analyse des Rechtsverhaltens, Berlin. Rowe, T.D. (1984), “Predicting the Effects of Attorney Fee Shifting”, Law and Contemporary Problems, Vol. 47, S. 139-171. Rowe, T.D. (1998), “Indemnity or Compensation? The Contract with America, Loser-Pays Attorney Fee Shifting, and a One-Way Alternative”, Washburn Law Journal, S. 317-344. Rowe, T.D. und D.A. Anderson (1996a), “One-Way Fee Shifting Statutes and Offer of Judgement Rules: An Experiment”, Jurimetrics, Vol. 36, S. 255-273. Rowe, T.D. und D.A. Anderson (1996b), “Empirical Research on the Success of Settlement Devices”, in: D.A. Anderson (Hrsg.), Dispute Resolution: Bridging the Settlement Gap. Rowe, T.D. und N. Vidmar (1988), “Empirical Research on Offers of Settlement: A Preliminary Report”, Law and Contemporary Problems, Vol. 51, S. 13-40. Rubinstein, A. (1982), “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model”, Econometrica, Vol. 50, S. 97-109. Rubinstein, A. (1985), “A Bargaining Model with Incomplete Information about Time Preferences”, Econometrica, Vol. 53, S. 1151-1172. Salant, W. und G. Rest (1982), “Litigation of Questioned Settlement Claims: A Bayesian Nash-Equilibrium Approach”, Rand Corporation Discussion Paper 6809. Samuelson, W. (1982), “Negotiation versus Litigation”, School of Management Working Paper 49/82. Schepens, T. (2007): “Bridging the Funding Gap – The Economics of Cost Shifting, Fee Arrangements and Legal Expenses Insurance and Their Prospects for Improving the Access to Civil Justice”, German Working Papers in Law and Economics, Article 1. Schmidtchen, D. und S. Weth (Hrsg.) (1999), Der Effizienz auf der Spur: Die Funktionsfähigkeit der Justiz im Lichte der ökonomischen Analyse des Rechts, Baden-Baden. Schwab, S. und T. Eisenberg (1988), “Explaining Constitutional Tort Litigation: The Influence of the Attorney Fees Statute and the Government as Defendant”, Cornell Law Review, Vol. 73, S. 719-784. Schweizer, U. (1989), “Litigation and Settlement under Two-Sided Incomplete Information”, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 56, S. 163-177. Shaphard, J.E. (1995), Likely Consequences of Amendments to Rule 68, Federal Judicial Center, Washington D. C. Shavell, S. (1982), “Suit, Settlement and Trial: A Theoretical Analysis under Alternative Methods for the Allocation of Legal Costs”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 11, S. 55-82. Shavell, S. (1996), “Any Frequency of Plaintiff Victory at Trial is Possible”, Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 25, S. 493-501. Shavell, S. (2004), Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law, Cambridge und London. Sherman, E.F. (1998), “From ‘Loser Pays’ to Modified Offer of Judgment Rules: Reconciling Incentives to Settle with Access to Justice”, Texas Law Review, Vol. 76, S. 1863-1896. Sieg, H. (2000), “Estimating a Bargaining Model with Asymmetric Information: Evidence from Medical Malpractice Disputes”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 108, S. 1006-1021. Snyder, E.A. und J.W. Hughes (1990), “The English Rule for Allocating Legal Costs: Evidence Confronts Theory”, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Vol. 6, S. 345-380. Spier, K.E. (1992), “The Dynamics of Pretrial Negotiation”, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 59, S. 93-108. Spier, K.E. (1994), “Pretrial Bargaining and the Design of Fee-Shifting Rules”, RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 25, S. 197-214. Toran, J. (1986), “Settlement, Sanctions, and Attorney Fees: Comparing English Payment into Court and Proposed Rule 68”, American University Law Review, Vol. 35, S. 301-338. Vargo, J.F. (1993), “The American Rule on Attorney Fee Allocation: The Injured Person's Access To Justice”, American University Law Review, Vol. 42, S. 1567-1636. Waldfogel, J. (1998), “Reconciling Asymmetric Information and Divergent Expectations Theories of Litigation”, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 41, S. 451-476. Wang, G.H., J.Y. Kim und J.G. Yi (1994), “Litigation and Pretrial Negotiation under Incomplete Information”, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Vol. 10, S. 187-200. Wasilewski, R. (1990), Streitverhütung durch Rechtsanwälte - Empirische Untersuchung von Umfang, Struktur und Bedingungen außergerichtlicher Beilegung zivilrechtlicher Streitigkeiten durch Rechtsanwälte, Köln. Williams, G.R. (1983), Legal Negotiation and Settlement, St. Paul, Minnesota. Wilson, M.J. (2005), “Failed Attempt to Undermine the Third Wave: Attorney Fee Shifting Movement in Japan”, Emory International Law Review, Vol. 19, S. 1457-1488. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/32746 |