Gabaix, Xavier and Laibson, David Isaac and Moloche, Guillermo and Stephen, Weinberg (2003): The allocation of attention: theory and evidence.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_47339.pdf Download (414kB) | Preview |
Abstract
A host of recent studies show that attention allocation has important economic consequences. This paper reports the first empirical test of a cost-benefit model of the endogenous allocation of attention. The model assumes that economic agents have finite mental processing speeds and cannot analyze all of the elements in complex problems. The model makes tractable predictions about attention allocation, despite the high level of complexity in our environment. The model successfully predicts the key empirical regularities of attention allocation measured in a choice experiment. In the experiment, decision time is a scarce resource and attention allocation is continuously measured using Mouselab. Subject choices correspond well to the quantitative predictions of the model, which are derived from cost-benefit and option-value principles.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | The allocation of attention: theory and evidence |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | attention, satisficing, Mouselab |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C9 - Design of Experiments D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty |
Item ID: | 47339 |
Depositing User: | Guillermo Moloche |
Date Deposited: | 01 Jun 2013 23:07 |
Last Modified: | 01 Oct 2019 18:11 |
References: | [1] Aragones, E., Gilboa, I., Postlewaite, A., and Schmeidler, D. (2003), “Accuracy vs. Simplicity: A Complex Trade-Off ” (Mimeo). [2] Camerer, C. (2003), Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction (Princeton: Princeton University Press). [3] Camerer, C. and Ho, T-H. (1999), “Experience Weighted Attraction Learning in Normal-Form Games”, Econometrica, 67, 837-874. [4] Camerer, C., Johnson, E.J., Rymon, T., and Sen, S. (1993), “Cognition and Framing in Sequential Bargaining for Gains and Losses”, in K. Binmore, A. Kirman, and P. Tani (eds.) Frontiers of Game Theory (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press), 1994, 27-47. [5] Camerer, C. and Lovallo, D. (1999), “Overconfidence and Excess Entry: an Experimental Approach”, American Economic Review, March, 89, 306-318. [6] Conlisk, J. (1996), “Why Bounded Rationality?” Journal of Economic Literature, June, 34 (2), 669-700. [7] Costa-Gomes, M., Crawford, V., and Broseta, B. (2001), “Cognition and Behavior in Normal-Form Games: An Experimental Study”, Econometrica, 69, 1193-1235. [8] Costa-Gomes, M. and Crawford, V. (2003), “Cognition and Behavior in Two Person Guessing Games: an Experimental Study” (Mimeo, University of California, San Diego). [9] Daniel, K., Hirshleifer, D., and Teoh, S.H. (2002), “Investor Psychology in Capital Markets: Evidence and Policy Implications”, Journal of Monetary Economics 49(1) ,139-209. [10] D’Avolio, G. and Nierenberg, E. (2003), “Investor Attention: Evidence from the Message Boards” (Mimeo, Harvard). [11] Della Vigna, S. and Pollet, J. (2003), “Attention, Demographic Changes, and the Stock Market” (Mimeo, University of California at Berkeley). [12] Erev, I. and Roth, A. (1998), “Predicting How People Play Games”, American Economic Review, September, 88(2), 848-81. [13] Gabaix, X. and Laibson, D. (2001), “The 6D Bias and the Equity Premium Puzzle”, in B. Bernanke and K. Rogoff (eds.) NBER Macroeconomics Annual , 257-312. [14] Gabaix, X. and Laibson, D. (2002), “Bounded Rationality and Directed Cognition,” (Mimeo, MIT and Harvard). [15] Gabaix, X. and Laibson, D. (2003), “Some Industrial Organization with Boundedly Rational Consumers”, (Mimeo, MIT and Harvard). [16] Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P. and the ABC Research Group (1999), Simple Heuristics that Make Us Smart (Oxford: Oxford University Press). [17] Gittins, J.C. (1979), “Bandit Processes and Dynamic Allocation Indices”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, B-41(2), 148-77. [18] Gumbau, F. (2003), “Inflation Persistence and Learning in General Equilibrium” (Mimeo, Harvard). [19] Hirshleifer, D., Lim, S.S., and Teoh, S.H. (2003), “Disclosure to a Credulous Audience: The Role of Limited Attention” (Mimeo). [20] Jehiel, P. (1995), “Limited Horizon Forecast in Repeated Alternate Games”, Journal of Economic Theory, 67, 497-519. [21] Johnson, E.J., Camerer, C., Sen, S., and Rymon, T. (2002), “Detecting Failures of Backward Induction: Monitoring Information Search in Sequential Bargaining”, Journal of Economic Theory, May 2002, 104(1), 16-47. [22] Kahneman, D. (1973), Attention and Effort (New Jersey: Prentice Hall Inc.). [23] Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1974), “Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases”, Science, 185, 1124-1131. [24] Lynch, A. (1996), “Decision Frequency and Synchronization Across Agents: Implications for Aggregate Consumption and Equity Returns”, Journal of Finance 51(4): 1479-97. [25] Mankiw, N.G. and Reis, R. (2002), “Sticky Information Versus Sticky Prices: a Proposal to Replace the New Keynesian Phillips Curve”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4), 1295-1328. [26] Massey, B. C. and Wu, G. (2002), “Detecting Regime Shifts: The Psychology of Over- and Underreaction” (Mimeo, University of Chicago Graduate School of Business). [27] Moray, N. (1959), “Attention in Dichotic Listening: Affective Cues and the Influence of Instructions”, Quarterly Journal of Experimental Psychology, 11, 56-60. [28] Pashler, H. (ed) (1998), Attention. (UK: Psychology Press). [29] Pashler, H. and Johnston, J.C. (1998), “Attentional Limitations in Dual Task Performance,” in H. Pashler (ed) Attention (UK: Psychology Press), 155-190. [30] Payne, J.W., Bettman, J.R, and Johnson, E.J. (1993), The Adaptive Decision Maker (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). [31] Payne, J.W), Braunstein, M.L., and Carroll, J.S. (1978), “Exploring Predecisional Behavior: an Alternative Approach to Decision Research”, Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 22, 17-44. [32] Peng, L. and Xiong, W. (2003) “Capacity Constrained Learning and Asset Price Comovement”, (Mimeo, Princeton). [33] Pollet, J. (2003), “Predicting Asset Returns with Expected Oil Price Changes” (Mimeo, Harvard). [34] Rogers L.C.G. (2001) “The relaxed investor and parameter uncertainty.” Finance and Stochastics 5(2): 131-54. [35] Russo, J. E. (1978), “Eye Fixations Can Save the World: a Critical Evaluation and a Comparison between Eye Fixations and Other Information Processing Methodologies”, Memory and Cognition, 3(3), 267-276. [36] Simon, H. (1955), “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Feb, 69(1), 99-118. [37] Sims, C. (2003), “Implications of Rational Inattention”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(3), 665-690. [38] Tversky, A. (1972), “Elimination by Aspects: A Theory of Choice”, Psychological Review, 79, 281-299. [39] Wegner, D.M. (1989), White Bears and Other Unwanted Thoughts: Suppression, Obsession, and the Psychology of Mental Control (New York: Viking/Penguin). [40] Weitzman, M. (1979), “Optimal Search for the Best Alternative”, Econometrica, 47(3), 641-54. [41] Weitzman, M. and Roberts, K. (1980), “On a General Approach to Search and Information Gathering”, MIT Working Paper 263. [42] Wood, N. and Cowan, N. (1995), “The Cocktail Party Phenomenon Revisited: How Frequent Are Attention Shifts to One’s Name in an Irrelevant Auditory Channel”, Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning Memory and Cognition, 21(1), 255-60. [43] Woodford, M. (2002),“Imperfect Common Knowledge and the Effects of Monetary Policy”, in P. Aghion, J. Stiglitz, and M. Woodford (eds.) Knowledge, Information, and Expectations in Modern Macroeconomics: in Honor of Edmund S. Phelps (Princeton: Princeton University Press). [44] Yantis, S. (1998), “Control of Visual Attention,” in Harold Pashler (ed.) Attention (UK: Psychology Press), 223-256. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/47339 |