Freeman, Alan (2013): The Road to Market Serfdom: Why Economics is Not a Science and How to Fix it.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_52677.pdf Download (231kB) | Preview |
Abstract
This paper was presented to the May 2013 conference of the Postglobalization Initiative in Moscow, and deals with the function of economics in the modern world order. It seeks to explain why, as a profession (notwithstanding individual exceptions) economics failed to predict the crisis that opened in 2007; why it then failed to foresee its length and depth; and why it proposes no solutions that could bring it to an end.
The paper challenges economics’ most fundamental claim, that it conducts itself as a science, arguing that it instead behaves as a religious system for making and justifying political decisions whose core belief is market perfection: the notion that the combination of private property in production with universal commodification is not only optimal, but cannot fail.
The paper proposes a radical new conception of the ethical duty of economists as resisting untruth, which it can do by conducting itself as a pluralist science. To this end, the paper introduces a distinction between two functions of knowledge: its exoteric function through which society arranges to control nature, and its esoteric function which organises, within a rational structure, systems of law, ethics, morality, and their relations to each other.
In science, the exoteric predominates over the esoteric. In religion, the reverse is the case. This explains the real function of economics, which is a disguised normative system rooted in the primary principle of market perfection. Its prescriptions are derived not by the normal scientific method of testing a variety of theories against the evidence, but by the elevation of this supposition into an unchallengeable dogma. It operates as a monotheoretic body of knowledge in which, at any given time and facing any given problem, only one unique answer is offered, denying the users of economics the basic democratic and scientific right to choose between a variety of answers on the basis of their own independent assessment of both the evidence and the presuppositions of the theories from which the prospective answers are deduced.
The primary mechanism of its religious function lie therefore in its methods of theoretical selection: it permits the promulgation and indeed, development, only of those theories which yield predictions consistent with the dogma of market perfection.
It is constructed to suppress any body of theory which leads to conclusions inconsistent with the assumption of market perfection, most notably those, such as the theories of Marx and Keynes, which demonstrate that the market system is self-contradictory – that is to say, that it acts so as to undermine the basis for its own existence. The more likely it is that a given theory may lead to such conclusions, the more thoroughly it is suppressed.
In consequence, those theories that escape the suppressive net of economics are precisely those in which the present social order is presented as not merely optimal but natural, inevitable and eternal. Interference with this market then becomes a crime against nature. All private benefits of the property-owners become the result of natural forces: they are rich because nature intended them to be. Take their riches from them, and things can only get worse. Poverty, destitution, famine: these are sad but inevitable consequences of nature. Any policy designed to offset or overcome them is misguided. Nature, in a word, has been enthroned as a God, by excluding humans from Nature.
I employ the term market serfdom to characterise such a system, because it removes choice from the field. Human agency is itself designated a crime against nature. Hayek and his followers, the paper, have erred in making an issue of the claim that ‘serfdom’ comes from interfering with the market: Actually they propose that they only course open to humanity is to submit to the market. His is the freedom of the slave who accepts his destiny. We have no choice but what the market ordains. Economics, as we now know it, is the theoretically perfected manifestation of this doctrine, just as late mediaeval Catholicism was the perfected manifestation of the doctrine of submission to the established aristocratic and monarchic order.
The paper then analyzes the two principal mechanisms by which the profession of economics has arrived at this point: selection for conformity and institutional delegitimation, and briefly outlines how ‘assertive pluralism’ could, if applied systematically, restore the study of political economy to the status of a science.
Slides, and a video of the presentation and discussion, will be made available through the link to this paper at https://londonmet.academia.edu/AlanFreeman
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Institution: | The University of Greenwich |
Original Title: | The Road to Market Serfdom: Why Economics is Not a Science and How to Fix it. |
English Title: | The Road to Market Serfdom: Why Economics is Not a Science and How to Fix it. |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Value, Price, Money, Labour, Marx, MELT, Okishio, TSSI, temporalism, rate of profit |
Subjects: | B - History of Economic Thought, Methodology, and Heterodox Approaches > B1 - History of Economic Thought through 1925 B - History of Economic Thought, Methodology, and Heterodox Approaches > B4 - Economic Methodology B - History of Economic Thought, Methodology, and Heterodox Approaches > B5 - Current Heterodox Approaches |
Item ID: | 52677 |
Depositing User: | Alan Freeman |
Date Deposited: | 04 Jan 2014 18:32 |
Last Modified: | 27 Sep 2019 01:51 |
References: | Barbour, Ian G (1990). Religion in an age of science, London: SCM. Chamberlain (2003) The Bad Popes, Sutton Publishing. Copernicus, N (1543) De revolutionibus orbium coelestium, published in English translation at <http://webexhibits.org/calendars/year-text-Copernicus.html> (accessed 23/2/2006) Davidson, P. (1991) Controversies in Post-Keynesian Economics, Aldershot and Vermont: Edward Elgar. Debreu, G (1959), Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press Drake, S (1980). Galileo.Oxford and New York: OUP. Eatwell, J, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman (1989) General Equilibrium, London and Basingstoke: McMillan. Ekeland, A(2006) ‘Haavelmo – a low key heterodox?’, paper submitted to the 2006 conference of the Association for Heterodox Economics. Fara, P (2002) Newton: The Making of Genius, Basingstoke and Oxford: McMillan Farringdon, B. (1939), Science and Politics in the Ancient World. London: George Allen and Unwin. Freeman (2004) ‘Science, religion and the reform of economics’, presented to the fourth annual conference of the Association of Heterodox Economists, Nottingham, July 2004. Freeman, A. and Guglielmo Carchedi (1995) Marx and Non-Equilibrium Economics, Aldershot and Vermont: Edward Elgar. Freeman, A. Andrew Kliman and Julian Wells (2004) The New Value Theory Controversy in Economics, Aldershot and Vermont: Edward Elgar. Jaffé, W (ed ) (1965) Correspondence of Léon Walras and related papers, Amsterdam: North Holland. Kliman, A and Freeman, A (2000) ‘Two Concepts of Value, Two Rates of Profit, Two Laws of Motion’ in Research in Political Economy 18. Kliman, A. (2006) Reclaiming Marx’s Capital: A Refutation of the Myth of Inconsistency. Lexington. Kuhn, T. S. (1962) The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press. Laibman, D. (2004) ‘Rhetoric and Substance in Value Theory: an Appraisal of the New Orthodox Marxism’ in Freeman, Kliman and Wells (eds) 2004, The New Value Controversy in Economics, Aldershot and Vermont: Edward Elgar. Lattis, J (1994) Between Copernicus and Galileo: Christopher Clavius and the Collapse of Ptolemaic Cosmology, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Manning, A (2003) Monopsony in Motion. Princeton: PUP O’Driscoll, G. and Mario J. Rizzo (1985), The Economics of Time and Ignorance, London and New York: Routledge. Okishio, Nobuo (1961) ‘Technical Changes and the Rate of Profit’, Kobe University Economic Review 7. pp 86-99. Ormerod, P (1994) The Death of Economics, London:Faber and Faber. Sambursky, P (1987:44) The Physical World of the Greeks, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Samuelson, P and William D Nordhaus (1992) Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill. Sobel, D (1999). Galileo’s Daughter. London and New York: Penguin. Sowell, T (1972) Say's Law, An Historical Analysis, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Townshend, H. (1937) ‘Liquidity-premium and the theory of value’, Economic Journal, vol. XLVII. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/52677 |