Xu, Jun (2013): A two-sided market model of optimal price structure for instant messenger. Published in: Journal of Applied Mathematics , Vol. 2013, (2013)
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_62960.pdf Download (178kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Instant messenger (IM) is one of the most popular Internet applications all over the world.This paper examines the pricing problem of IM based on two-sided market model. IM serves as a two-sided platform, which gets both Internet users and advertisers on board. This paper concludes that IM operator adopts a heavily skewed price structure that favors IM users both under monopolistic case and under horizontal differentiated duopolistic case.When advertising revenue is large enough relatively to marginal cost for serving IM users, IM users can enjoy free service provided by IM operators.The competitive equilibrium of duopolistic case is not necessarily symmetric when advertisers choose singlehoming. Even in the symmetric equilibrium platform would rather deter all advertisers.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | A two-sided market model of optimal price structure for instant messenger |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Instant messenger; price structure; two-sided market |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D4 - Market Structure, Pricing, and Design > D43 - Oligopoly and Other Forms of Market Imperfection L - Industrial Organization > L1 - Market Structure, Firm Strategy, and Market Performance > L11 - Production, Pricing, and Market Structure ; Size Distribution of Firms |
Item ID: | 62960 |
Depositing User: | Jun Xu |
Date Deposited: | 20 Mar 2015 13:37 |
Last Modified: | 05 Oct 2019 04:50 |
References: | [1] A. C. Beattie, “Marketers eye webchat,” Advertising Age, vol. 84, no.8, pp. 20–20, 2013. [2] A. Spiegel, “Microsoft to buy skype for $8.5 billion: how to not screw it up,” Forbes.com, pp. 27–37. [3] T. I. M. Woodall, “Connecting the world,” Strad, vol. 124, no.1473, pp. 56–60, 2013. [4] J.-C. Rochet and J. Tirole, “Platform competition in two-sided markets,” Journal of the European Economic Association, vol. 1, no. 4, pp. 990–1029, 2003. [5] M. Armstrong, “Competition in two-sided markets,” RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 37, no. 3, pp. 668–691, 2006. [6] J.-C. Rochet and J. Tirole, “Two-sided markets: a progress report,” RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 37, no. 3, pp. 645–667, 2006. [7] W. Bolt and A. F. Tieman, “Heavily skewed pricing in two-sided markets,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol.26, no. 5, pp. 1250–1255, 2008. [8] A. Hagiu, “Two-sided platforms: product variety and pricing structures,” Journal of Economics & Management strategy, vol. 18, no. 4, pp. 1011–1043, 2009. [9] E. G.Weyl, “A price theory of multi-sided platforms,” American Economic Review, vol. 100, no. 3, pp. 1642–1672, 2010. [10] M. Armstrong and J.Wright, “Two-sided markets, competitive bottlenecks and exclusive contracts,” Economic Theory, vol. 32, no. 2, pp. 353–380, 2007. [11] D. S. Evans, “The antitrust economics of multi-sided platform markets,” Yale Journal on Regulation, vol. 20, no. 2, pp. 325–381, 2003. [12] S. P. Anderson and J. J.Gabszewicz, “The media and advertising: a tale of two-sided markets,” in Handbook of Cultural Economics, V. Ginsburgh and D. Throsby, Eds., vol. 1, Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2005. [13] S. P. Anderson and S. Coate, “Market provision of broadcasting: a welfare analysis,” Review of Economic Studies, vol. 72, no. 3, pp.947–972, 2005. [14] M. Peitz and T. M. Valletti, “Content and advertising in the media: pay-tv versus free-to-air,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol. 26, no. 4, pp. 949–965, 2008. [15] E. Gal-Or and A. Dukes, “Minimum differentiation in commercial media markets,”Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, vol. 12, no. 3, pp. 291–325, 2003. [16] J. Gabszewicz, D. Laussel, and N. Sonnac, “TV broadcasting competition and advertising,” CORE Discussion Papers 2000006, 2001. [17] M. Reisinger, “Platform competition for advertisers and users in media markets,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol. 32, no. 2, pp. 243–252, 2012. [18] G. Faulhaber, “Network effects and merger analysis: instant messaging and the AOL-time warner case,” Telecommunications Policy, vol. 26, no. 5-6, pp. 311–333, 2002. [19] J. Kim, S. H. Bang, and S. Hwang, “Anti-competitiveness of instant messenger tying by microsoft,” Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics, vol. 52, no. 2, pp. 185–198, 2011. [20] J.-C. Rochet and J. Wright, “Credit card interchange fees,” Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 24, no. 8, pp. 1788–1797, 2010. [21] R. Gil and W. R. Hartmann, “Empirical analysis of metering price discrimination: evidence from concession sales at movie theaters,” Marketing Science, vol. 28, no. 6, pp. 1046–1062, 2009. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/62960 |