Glötzl, Erhard (2015): Why and How to overcome General Equilibrium Theory.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_66265.pdf Download (1MB) | Preview |
Abstract
For more than 100 years economists have tried to describe economics in analogy to physics, more precisely to classical Newtonian mechanics. The development of the Neoclassical General Equilibrium Theory has to be understood as the result of these efforts. But there are many reasons why General Equilibrium Theory is inadequate: 1. No true dynamics. 2. The assumption of the existence of utility functions and the possibility to aggregate them to one “Master” utility function. 3. The impossibility to describe situations as in “Prisoners Dilemma”, where individual optimization does not lead to a collective optimum. This paper aims at overcoming these problems. It illustrates how not only equilibria of economic systems, but also the general dynamics of these systems can be described in close analogy to classical mechanics.
To this end, this paper makes the case for an approach based on the concept of constrained dynamics, analyzing the economy from the perspective of “economic forces” and “economic power” based on the concept of physical forces and the reciprocal value of mass. Realizing that accounting identities constitute constraints in the economy, the concept of constrained dynamics, which is part of the standard models of classical mechanics, can be applied to economics. Therefore it is reasonable to denote such models as Newtonian Constraint Dynamic Models (NCD-Models).
Such a framework allows understanding both Keynesian and neoclassical models as special cases of NCD-Models in which the power relationships with respect to certain variables are one-sided. As mixed power relationships occur more frequently in reality than purely one-sided power constellations, NCD-models are better suited to describe the economy than standard Keynesian or Neoclassic models.
A NCD-model can be understood as “Continuous Time”, “Stock Flow Consistent”, “Agent Based Model”, where the behavior of the agents is described with a general differential equation for every agent. In the special case where the differential equations can be described with utility functions, the behavior of every agent can be understood as an individual optimization strategy. He thus seeks to maximize his utility. However, while the core assumption of neoclassical models is that due to the “invisible hand” such egoistic individual behavior leads to an optimal result for all agents, reality is often defined by “Prisoners Dilemma” situations, in which individual optimization leads to the worst outcome for all. One advantage of NCD-models over standard models is that they are able to describe also such situations, where an individual optimization strategy does not lead to an optimum result for all agents. This will be illustrated in a simple example.
In conclusion, the big merit and effort of Newton was, to formalize the right terms (physical force, inertial mass, change of velocity) and to set them into the right relation. Analogously the appropriate terms of economics are force, economic power and change of flow variables. NCD-Models allow formalizing them and setting them into the right relation to each other.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Why and How to overcome General Equilibrium Theory |
English Title: | Why and How to overcome General Equilibrium Theory |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Newtonian Constrained Dynamics, Disequilibrium Dynamics, Economics of Power, Closure, Prisoners Dilemma, Economics and Physics |
Subjects: | B - History of Economic Thought, Methodology, and Heterodox Approaches > B2 - History of Economic Thought since 1925 > B22 - Macroeconomics B - History of Economic Thought, Methodology, and Heterodox Approaches > B4 - Economic Methodology > B41 - Economic Methodology C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C0 - General > C02 - Mathematical Methods C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C6 - Mathematical Methods ; Programming Models ; Mathematical and Simulation Modeling > C60 - General C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory > C72 - Noncooperative Games E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E1 - General Aggregative Models > E10 - General |
Item ID: | 66265 |
Depositing User: | Erhard Glötzl |
Date Deposited: | 25 Aug 2015 15:21 |
Last Modified: | 28 Sep 2019 19:23 |
References: | Arrow, K. J., & Debreu, G. (1954). Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy. Econometrica, 22(3), 265–290. BarBosa-FilHo, N. N. H. (2004). A Simple Model of Demand-Led Growth and Income Distribution. Revista Economica, 5(3), 17–154. Blanchard, O., & Illing, G. (2009). Makroökonomie. München [u.a.]: Pearson Studium. Böhm-Bawerk, E. (1914). Macht oder ökonomisches Gesetz? Zeitschrift Für Volkswirtschaft, Sozialpolitik Und Verwaltung, 23, 205–271. Cooper, J. B. (2010). On Paul Samuelson, Lind and the holy grail equation. Internationale Mathematische Nachrichten, 213, 1–5. Cooper, J. B., & Russell, T. (2011). On the mathematics of thermodynamics. Cvitanic, J. & Zhang, J. (2011) Contract Theory in Continous-Time Models, Springer. Foley, D. K. (1986). Understanding capital : Marx’s economic theory. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Giza, W. (2013). Adam Smiths unsichtbare Hand und das Gefangenendilemma. Orientierungen Zur Wirtschafts- Und Gesellschaftspolitik, 135(1), 47–50. Glötzl, E. (1999). Wechselfieber der Volkswirtschaften. Zeitschrift für Sozialökonomie, 121. Kaldor, N. (1956). Alternative Theories of Distribution. The Review of Economic Studies, 23(2), 83–100. Kümmel, R. (2011). The second law of economics: energy, entropy, and the origins of wealth. New York, N.Y.: Springer. Marglin, S. A. (1987). Growth, Distribution and Prices. Harvard University Press. Mirowski, P. (1989). More heat than light: economics as social physics, physics as nature’s economics. Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press. Nash, J. (1951). Non-Cooperative Games. The Annals of Mathematics, 54(2), 286. Prince, G. E., & King, D. (2007). The inverse problem in the calculus of variations : nonexistence of Lagrangians. In Differential geometric methods in mechanics and field theory (pp. 131–140). Ghent, Belgium: Academia Press. Redman, D. (1993). Adam Smith and Isaac Newton. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 40(2). Rothschild, K. W. (2002). The absence of power in contemporary economic theory. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 31(5), 433–442. Russell, B. (1938). Power: A New Social Analysis. London: Goerge Allen & Unwin. Sannikov, Y. (2012), 10th World Congress of Econometric Society, Princeton University. Santilli, R. M. (1978). Foundations of theoretical mechanics. New York: Springer-Verlag. Sen, A. (1963). Neo-classical and Neo-keynesian theories of distribution. Economic Record, 39, 53–64. Smith, A. (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (5th, 1904th ed.). London: Methuen & Co., Ltd. Smith, A. (1795). Essays on Philosophical Subjects. In History of Astronomy. London. Smith, E., & Foley, D. K. (2008). Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium theory. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 32(1), 7–65. Taylor, L. (1991). Income Distribution, Inflation, and Growth: Lectures on Structuralist Macroeconomic Theory. MIT Press. Walras, L. (1874). Éléments d’économie politique pure; ou, Théorie de la richesse sociale. Lausanne. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/66265 |