Wang, Weijia (2019): A Pareto Criterion on Systemic Risk.
PDF
MPRA_paper_93909.pdf Download (218kB) |
Abstract
Perfect risk sharing is not an optimal design for the financial system because it can increase systemic risk by facilitating risk contagion among financial institutions. However, risk sharing dominates betting according to most Pareto efficiency criteria. One reason for this might be that those Pareto criteria consider individual risk rather than systemic risk and neglect that betting may reduce systemic risk by segmenting the financial system and preventing financial contagion. Refining Pareto criterion to cover systemic risk, I propose the systemic Pareto criterion which has two features: 1) satisfying facts that betting dominates risk sharing when systemic risk is considered. 2) being applicable to scenarios with the constant aggregate endowment to which current criteria cannot provide compelling suggestions. One implication from this paper is that betting can act as the stabilizer of the economy and prohibiting betting is not always helpful for financial stability.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | A Pareto Criterion on Systemic Risk |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Risk Sharing, Heterogenous Beliefs, Pareto Efficiency, Systemic Risk |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D6 - Welfare Economics > D61 - Allocative Efficiency ; Cost-Benefit Analysis D - Microeconomics > D6 - Welfare Economics > D62 - Externalities G - Financial Economics > G1 - General Financial Markets > G18 - Government Policy and Regulation |
Item ID: | 93909 |
Depositing User: | Weijia Wang |
Date Deposited: | 14 May 2019 14:29 |
Last Modified: | 28 Sep 2019 16:34 |
References: | Acemoglu, D., Ozdaglar, A., and Tahbaz-Salehi, A. (2015). Systemic risk and stability in financial networks. American Economic Review, 105(2):564– 608. Allen, F., Babus, A., and Carletti, E. (2012). Asset commonality, debt maturity and systemic risk. Journal of Financial Economics, 104(3):519– 534. Alon, S. and Gayer, G. (2016). Utilitarian preferences with multiple priors. Econometrica, 84(3):1181–1201. Back, K. (2010). Asset pricing and portfolio choice theory. Oxford University Press. Battigalli, P. and Bonanno, G. (1997). The logic of belief persistence. Eco- nomics & Philosophy, 13(1):39–59. Battiston, S., Gatti, D. D., Gallegati, M., Greenwald, B., and Stiglitz, J. E. (2012). Liaisons dangereuses: Increasing connectivity, risk sharing, and systemic risk. Journal of economic dynamics and control, 36(8):1121–1141. Beale, N., Rand, D. G., Battey, H., Croxson, K., May, R. M., and Nowak, M. A. (2011). Individual versus systemic risk and the regulator’s dilemma. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(31):12647–12652. Brunnermeier, M. K., Simsek, A., and Xiong, W. (2014). A welfare criterion for models with distorted beliefs. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(4):1753–1797. Castiglionesi, F., Feriozzi, F., and Lorenzoni, G. (2017). Financial integration and liquidity crises. Management Science, 65(3):955–975. Danan, E., Gajdos, T., Hill, B., and Tallon, J.-M. (2016). Robust social decisions. American Economic Review, 106(9):2407–25. Dasgupta, A. (2004). Financial contagion through capital connections: A model of the origin and spread of bank panics. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(6):1049–1084. Foote, C. L., Gerardi, K. S., and Willen, P. S. (2012). Why did so many people make so many ex post bad decisions? the causes of the foreclosure crisis. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research. Gilboa, I., Samet, D., and Schmeidler, D. (2004). Utilitarian aggregation of beliefs and tastes. Journal of Political Economy, 112(4):932–938. Gilboa, I., Samuelson, L., and Schmeidler, D. (2014). No-betting-pareto dominance. Econometrica, 82(4):1405–1442. Haldane, A. G. and May, R. M. (2011). Systemic risk in banking ecosystems. Nature, 469(7330):351. Hammond, P. J. (1981). Ex-ante and ex-post welfare optimality under un- certainty. Economica, 48(191):235–250. Harsanyi, J. C. (1955). Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics, and interper- sonal comparisons of utility. Journal of political economy, 63(4):309–321. Ko, K. J. and Huang, Z. (2012). Persistence of beliefs in an investment experiment. The Quarterly Journal of Finance, 2(01):1250005. Mongin, P. (2016). Spurious unanimity and the pareto principle. Economics & Philosophy, 32(3):511–532. Nielsen, C. K. (2003). Floating exchange rates versus a monetary union under rational beliefs: the role of endogenous uncertainty. Economic Theory, 21(2-3):293–315. Nielsen, C. K. (2018). Rational overconfidence and social security: subjective beliefs, objective welfare. Economic Theory, 65(2):179–229. Savage, L. J. (1972). The foundations of statistics. Courier Corporation. Stiglitz, J. E. (2010a). Contagion, liberalization, and the optimal structure of globalization. Journal of Globalization and Development, 1(2). Stiglitz, J. E. (2010b). Risk and global economic architecture: Why full financial integration may be undesirable. American Economic Review, 100(2):388–92. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/93909 |
Available Versions of this Item
-
A Pareto Criterion on Systemic Risk. (deposited 08 May 2019 13:19)
- A Pareto Criterion on Systemic Risk. (deposited 14 May 2019 14:29) [Currently Displayed]