Tang, Rongsheng (2021): Market Formation in China from 1978.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_105510.pdf Download (468kB) | Preview |
Abstract
This paper studies the formation of market economy in China from 1978 to 1992, a period in which market economy was introduced and developed alongside planned government procurements for agricultural goods. Under the “dual track system” (DTS), rural farmers were obligated to fulfill government procurements before selling to the market, whereas urban consumers enjoyed de facto subsidies to agricultural products. Using a neoclassical general equilibrium model with heterogeneous firms and workers and input-output linkage, this paper exploits historical data and analyzes allocation, prices, and the formation of markets in China during this DTS period. Theoretically, while DTS will distort the resources allocation between rural and urban (misallocation effect), it selects workers and farmers in the rural (selection effect). What is more, comparing to the economy under Soviet-style big bang reform, DTS activates industrialization by providing intermediate goods with lower-than-market price (activation effect). Quantitatively, directly switching to market economy in 1978 would decrease total output by 4.5% as the activation effect dominates. On the intensive margin, reform on DTS ( procurement price was getting closer to market price ) had contributed to total output by 4.4% from 1978 to 1992.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Market Formation in China from 1978 |
English Title: | Market Formation in China from 1978 |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Dual Track System; procurement; price distortion; misallocation |
Subjects: | E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E6 - Macroeconomic Policy, Macroeconomic Aspects of Public Finance, and General Outlook > E65 - Studies of Particular Policy Episodes N - Economic History > N1 - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics ; Industrial Structure ; Growth ; Fluctuations > N10 - General, International, or Comparative O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O4 - Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity > O43 - Institutions and Growth O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O5 - Economywide Country Studies > O53 - Asia including Middle East |
Item ID: | 105510 |
Depositing User: | Dr. Rongsheng Tang |
Date Deposited: | 26 Jan 2021 14:30 |
Last Modified: | 26 Jan 2021 14:30 |
References: | Adamopoulos, Tasso and Diego Restuccia, “The size Distortion of Farms and International Productivity Differences,” American Economic Review, 2014, 104 (6), 1667–97. -, Loren Brandt, Jessica Leight, and Diego Restuccia, “Misallocation, selection and productivity: A quantitative analysis with panel data from China,” Technical Report, National Bureau of Economic Research 2017. Brandt, Loren and Xiaodong Zhu, “Accounting for China’s Growth,” 2010. -, Gueorgui Kambourov, and Kjetil Storesletten, “Barriers to Entry and Regional Economic Growth in China,” Working paper, 2018. Buera, Francisco J, Joseph P Kaboski, and Yongseok Shin, “Finance and Development: A Tale of Two Sectors,” The American Economic Review, 2011, 101 (5),19–64. Byrd, William A, The market mechanism and economic reforms in China, ME Sharpe Armonk, NY, 1991. Chen, Chaoran, “Untitled land, occupational choice, and agricultural productivity,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2017, 9 (4), 91–121. Cheremukhin, Anton, Mikhail Golosov, Sergei Guriev, and Aleh Tsyvinski, “The industrialization and economic development of Russia through the lens of a neoclassical growth model,” The Review of Economic Studies, 2017, 84 (2), 613–649. Guriev, Sergei, “Gorbachev versus Deng: AReview of Chris Miller’s The Struggle to Save the Soviet Economy,” Journal of Economic Literature, 2019, 57 (1), 120–46. Hsieh, Chang-Tai and Peter J. Klenow, “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2009, 124 (4), 1403–1448. Jin, Hehui and Yingyi Qian, “Public versus private ownership of firms: Evidence from rural China,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1998, 113 (3), 773–808. Jones, Charles I, “Intermediate goods and weak links in the theory of economic development,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2011, pp. 1–28. Lagakos, David and Michael EWaugh, “Selection, agriculture, and cross-country productivity differences,” American Economic Review, 2013, 103 (2), 948–80. Lau, Lawrence J, Yingyi Qian, and Gerard Roland, “Reform without losers: An interpretation of China’s dual-track approach to transition,” Journal of Political Economy, 2000, 108 (1), 120–143. Li, Wei, “The impact of economic reform on the performance of Chinese state enterprises, 1980–1989,” Journal of Political Economy, 1997, 105 (5), 1080–1106. -, “A tale of two reforms,” The RAND Journal of Economics, 1999, pp. 120–136. Liu, Ernest, “Industrial policies in production networks,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2019, 134 (4), 1883–1948. McMillan, John and Barry Naughton, “How to reform a planned economy: lessons from China,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 1992, 8 (1), 130–143. -, John Whalley, and Lijing Zhu, “The impact of China’s economic reforms on agricultural productivity growth,” The Journal of Political Economy, 1989, pp. 781–807. Midrigan, Virgiliu and Daniel Yi Xu, “Finance and misallocation: Evidence from plant-level data,” The American Economic Review, 2014, 104 (2), 422–458. Murphy, Kevin M, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W Vishny, “The transition to a market economy: Pitfalls of partial reform,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1992, 107 (3), 889–906. Naughton, Barry, “Chinese institutional innovation and privatization from below,” The American Economic Review:P&P, 1994, 84 (2), 266–270. Qian, Yingyi and Chenggang Xu, “The M-form hierarchy and China’s economic reform,” European Economic Review, 1993, 37 (2-3), 541–548. Restuccia, Diego and Richard Rogerson, “The Causes and Costs of Misallocation,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, August 2017, 31 (3), 151–74. -, Dennis Tao Yang, and Xiaodong Zhu, “Agriculture and aggregate productivity: A quantitative cross-country analysis,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 2008, 55 (2), 234–250. Roland, Gérard and Thierry Verdier, “Law enforcement and transition,” European Economic Review, 2003, 47 (4), 669–685. Sachs, Jeffrey and Wing Thye Woo, “Structural factors in the economic reforms of China, Eastern Europe, and the former Soviet Union,” Economic policy, 1994, 9 (18), 101–145. Sicular, Terry, “Plan and market in China’s agricultural commerce,” The Journal of Political Economy, 1988, pp. 283–307. -, “Redefining state, plan and market: China’s reforms in agricultural commerce,” The China Quarterly, 1995, 144, 1020–1046. Song, Zheng, Kjetil Storesletten, and Fabrizio Zilibotti, “Growing like china,” The American Economic Review, 2011, 101 (1), 196–233. Young, Alwyn, “The razor’s edge: Distortions and incremental reform in the People’s Republic of China,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2000, 115 (4), 1091–1135. Zhu, Xiaodong, “Understanding China’s growth: Past, present, and future,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2012, 26 (4), 103–24. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/105510 |