Raveh, Ohad and Perez-Sebastian, Fidel and van der Ploeg, Frederick (2024): Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? The Role of Natural Resources.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_120355.pdf Download (601kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Are technology improvements contractionary? We re-examine this central question, accounting for the presence of natural resources. A two-sector model of economic growth indicates that capital-augmenting technological improvements can be contemporaneously contractionary in resource-rich economies, and expansionary elsewhere, due to differences in the size of the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital. In addition, such improvements yield relatively steeper expansionary patterns in resource-rich economies in the longer run. We test our analytical predictions using a panel of U.S. states and counties. Our identification strategy rests on geographically-entrenched differences in resource endowments, and the adoption of plausibly exogenous technology shocks at the national level. Our core estimates corroborate our predictions. First, we document persistent differences in the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital across the natural resources dimension. Second, we find that an increase in TFP is on impact contractionary in resource-rich states, yet is non-contractionary (at worst) in resource-poor ones. Third, we illustrate that in the longer term a positive technology shock expands output and inputs in resource-rich economies relatively more strongly. Our results shed light on hitherto overlooked potential adverse effects of natural resource abundance.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? The Role of Natural Resources |
English Title: | Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? The Role of Natural Resources |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Natural resource abundance, technology shocks, input elasticities |
Subjects: | O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O3 - Innovation ; Research and Development ; Technological Change ; Intellectual Property Rights > O33 - Technological Change: Choices and Consequences ; Diffusion Processes Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics ; Environmental and Ecological Economics > Q3 - Nonrenewable Resources and Conservation > Q32 - Exhaustible Resources and Economic Development |
Item ID: | 120355 |
Depositing User: | Ohad Raveh |
Date Deposited: | 18 Mar 2024 12:09 |
Last Modified: | 18 Mar 2024 12:09 |
References: | Allcott, H. and D. Keniston (2018): “Dutch disease or agglomeration? The local economic effects of natural resource booms in modern America,” Review of Economic Studies, 85, 596–731. Antras, P. (2004): “Is the U.S. aggregate production function Cobb-Douglas? New estimates of the elasticity of substitution,” Contributions in Macroeconomics, 4, 20121005. Arezki, R., A. V. Ramey, and L. Sheng (2017): “News shocks in open economies: Evidence from giant oil discoveries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132, 103–155. Armand, A., A. Coutts, P. Vicente, and I. Vilela (2020): “Does information break the political resource curse? Experimental evidence from Mozambique,” American Economic Review, 110, 3431–3453. Balistreri, E. J., C. A. McDaniel, and E. V. Wong (2003): “An estimation of U.S. industry-level capital–labor substitution elasticities: Support for Cobb–Douglas,” The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 14, 343–356. Barsky, R. B. and E. R. Sims (2011): “News shocks and business cycles,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 58, 273–289. Basu, S., G. J. Fernald, and S. M. Kimball (2006): “Are technology improvements contractionary?” American Economic Review, 96, 1418–1448. Bhattacharyya, S. and R. Hodler (2010): “Natural resources, democracy and corruption,” European Economic Review, 54, 608–621. Bils, M. (1998): “Discussion of technology and business cycles: How well do standard models explain the facts?” Federal Reserve Bank of Boson Conference Series 42, Beyond Shocks: What Causes Business Cycles, 255-263. Brollo, F., T. Nannicini, R. Perotti, and G. Tabellini (2013): “The political resource curse,” American Economic Review, 103, 1759–1796. Caballero, R. J. (1994): “Small sample bias and adjustment costs,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 52–58. Caballero, R. J., E. M. Engel, J. C. Haltiwanger, M. Woodford, and R. E. Hall (1995): “Plant-level adjustment and aggregate investment dynamics,” Brookings papers on economic activity, 1–54. Caselli, F. and I. Coleman, Wilbur John (2006): “The world technology frontier,” American Economic Review, 96, 499–522. Chang, Y. and J. H. Hong (2006): “Do technological improvements in the manufacturing sector raise or lower employment?” American Economic Review, 96, 352–368. Chirinko, R. S. (2008): “σ: The long and short of it,” Journal of Macroeconomics, 30, 671–686. Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and R. Vigfusson (2004): “The response of hours to a technology shock: Evidence based on direct measures of technology,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 381–395. 33 Doraszelski, U. and J. Jaumandreu (2013): “R&D and productivity: Estimating endogenous productivity,” Review of economic studies, 80, 1338–1383. Duffy, J., C. Papageorgiou, and F. Perez-Sebastian (2004): “Capital-skill complementarity? Evidence from a panel of countries,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 86, 327–344. Fernald, J. (2014): “A quarterly, utilization-adjusted series on Total Factor Productivity,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2012-19. Francis, N., M. T. Owyang, J. E. Roush, and R. DiCecio (2014): “A flexible finitehorizon alternative to long-run restrictions with an application to technology shocks,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 96, 638–647. Gali, J. (1999): “Technology, employment, and the business cycle: Do technology shocks explain aggregate fluctuations?” American Economic Review, 89, 249–271. Garofalo, G. and S. Yamarik (2002): “Regional convergence: Evidence from a new stateby- state capital stock series,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 84, 316–323. Groth, C. and H. Khan (2010): “Investment adjustment costs: An empirical assessment,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42, 1469–1494. Gylfason, T. (2001): “Natural resources, education and economic development,” European Economic Review, 4, 847–859. Gylfason, T., T. T. Herbertsson, and G. Zoega (1999): “A mixed blessing: Natural resources and economic growth,” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 3, 204–225. Hicks, J. R. (1932): “The theory of wages,” London: Macmillan and Co. James, A. (2015): “U.S. state fiscal policy and natural resources,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 7, 238–257. James, A. and B. Smith (2017): “There will be blood: Crime rates in shale-rich U.S. counties,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 84, 125–152. Jorda, O. (2005): “Estimation and inference of impulse responses by local projections,” American Economic Review, 95, 161–182. Justiniano, A., G. E. Primiceri, and A. Tambalotti (2011): “Investment shocks and the relative price of investment,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 14, 102–121, special issue: Sources of Business Cycles. Klump, R., P. McAdam, and A. Willman (2007): “Factor substitution and factoraugmenting technical progress in the U.S.: A normalized supply-side system approach,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 89, 183–192. Krugman, P. (1987): “The narrow moving band, the Dutch disease, and the competitive consequences of Mrs. Thatcher: Notes on trade in the presence of dynamic scale economies,” Journal of Development Economics, 27, 41–55. Krusell, P., L. E. Ohanian, J.-V. R´ıos-Rull, and G. L. Violante (2000): “Capitalskill complementarity and inequality: A macroeconomic analysis,” Econometrica, 68, 1029– 1053. Kuralbayeva, K. and R. Stefanski (2013): “Windfalls, structural transformation and specialization,” Journal of International Economics, 90, 273–301. Kydland, F. E. and E. C. Prescott (1982): “Time to build and aggregate fluctuations,” Econometrica, 1345–1370. Le´on-Ledesma, M. A., P. McAdam, and A. Willman (2010): “Identifying the elasticity of substitution with biased technical change,” American Economic Review, 100, 1330–1357. Liu, C. and N. Williams (2019): “State-level implications of federal tax policies,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 105, 74–90. Michaels, G. (2011): “The long term consequences of resource-based specialisation,” Economic Journal, 121, 31–57. Michaels, G., A. Natraj, and J. Van Reenen (2014): “Has ICT polarized skill demand? Evidence from eleven countries over 25 years,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 96, 60–77. O’Mahony, M. and M. P. Timmer (2009): “Output, input and productivity measures at the industry level: The EUKLEMS database,” Economic Journal, 119, F374–F403. Perez-Sebastian, F., O. Raveh, and Y. Reingewertz (2019): “Heterogeneous vertical tax externalities and macroeconomic effects of federal tax changes: The role of fiscal advantage,” Journal of Urban Economics, 112, 85–110. Raval, D. R. (2019): “The micro elasticity of substitution and non-neutral technology,” RAND Journal of Economics, 50, 147–167. Raveh, O. (2013): “Dutch disease, factor mobility, and the Alberta Effect - The case of federations,” Canadian Journal of Economics, 46, 1317–1350. ——— (2020): “Monetary policy, natural resources, and federal redistribution,” Environmental and Resource Economics, 75, 585–613. Raveh, O. and A. Reshef (2016): “Capital imports composition, complementarities, and the skill premium in developing countries,” Journal of Development Economics, 118, 183–206. Sachs, J. D. and A. M. Warner (2001): “The curse of natural resources,” European economic review, 45, 827–838. Sat¯o, K. (1975): Production Functions and Aggregation, vol. 90. Stijns, J.-P. (2006): “Natural resource abundance and human capital accumulation,” World Development, 34, 1060–1083. Tornell, A. and P. Lane (1999): “The voracity effect,” American Economic Review, 89, 22–46. Torvik, R. (2001): “Learning by doing and the Dutch disease,” European Economic Review, 45, 285–306. ——— (2002): “Natural resources, rent seeking and welfare,” Journal of Development Economics, 67, 455–470. Van der Ploeg, F. (2011): “Natural resources: Curse or blessing?” Journal of Economic Literature, 49, 366–420. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/120355 |