Li, Jianpei and Zhang, Wanzhu (2025): The Value of Anonymous Option.
This is the latest version of this item.
![]() |
PDF
MPRA_paper_125628.pdf Download (580kB) |
Abstract
Privacy regulations require that sellers obtain explicit consumer consent before collecting personal data. We offer a novel analysis of this requirement by introducing an anonymous option into a repeated-purchase model with limited commitment in which consumers need to be incentivized to disclose their data. We show that despite full surplus extraction through data collection, a monopolist generally benefits from offering the option, as it changes market segmentation, credibly supports a high second-period uniform price, and mitigates the ratchet effect. However, the option may reduce consumer surplus and social welfare due to higher average prices and lower aggregate demand.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | The Value of Anonymous Option |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | anonymous option; data disclosure; personalized pricing; privacy regulations |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D4 - Market Structure, Pricing, and Design D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty L - Industrial Organization > L1 - Market Structure, Firm Strategy, and Market Performance |
Item ID: | 125628 |
Depositing User: | Dr. Wanzhu Zhang |
Date Deposited: | 12 Aug 2025 12:57 |
Last Modified: | 12 Aug 2025 12:57 |
References: | [1] Acquisti, A., C. Taylor, L. Wagman (2016): “The economics of privacy,” Journal of Economic Literature. 54(2): 442-492. [2] Acquisti A, HR. Varian (2005): “Conditioning prices on purchase history,” Marketing Science. 24(3): 367-381. [3] Argenziano R, A. Bonatti (2023): “Data markets with privacy-conscious consumers,” AEA Papers and Proceedings. 113: 191-196. [4] Argenziano R, A. Bonatti (2024): “Data linkage and privacy regulation,” American Economic Review, forthcoming. [5] Aridor G., Y-K. Che, T. Salz (2023): “The effect of privacy regulation on the data industry: empirical evidence from GDPR,” RAND Journal of Economics. 54(4): 695-730. [6] Ali, S. N., G. Lewis, S. Vasserman (2023): “Voluntary disclosure and personalized pricing,” Review of Economic Studies. 90(2): 538-571. [7] Belleflamme, P., W. Vergote (2016): “Monopoly price discrimination and privacy: The hidden cost of hiding,” Economics Letters. 149: 141-144. [8] Bergemann, D., A. Bonatti, A., T. Gan (2022): “The economics of social data,” RAND Journal of Economics. 53(2): 263-296. [9] Calzolari, G., A. Pavan (2006): “On the optimality of privacy in sequential contracting,” Journal of Economic Theory. 130: 168-204. [10] Choe, C., N. Matsushima, S. Shekhar (2025): “The bright side of the GDPR: Welfare-improving privacy management,” Management Science, forthcoming. [11] Choi J P., DS. Jeon, BC. Kim (2019): “Privacy and personal data collection with information externalities,” Journal of Public Economics. 173: 113-124. [12] Cong, J., N. Matsushima (2023): “The effects of personal data management on competition and welfare,” ISER Discussion Paper 1201. [13] Conitzer, V., CR. Taylor, L. Wagman (2012): “Hide and seek: costly consumer privacy in a market with repeat purchases,” Marketing Science. 31(2): 277–292. [14] Courty P, L. Hao (2000): “Sequential screening,” Review of Economic Studies. 67(4): 697-717. [15] Dengler, S., J. Prufer ¨ (2021): “Consumers’ privacy choices in the era of big data,” Games and Economic Behavior. 130: 499-520. [16] Doval, L., V. Skreta (2022): “Purchase history and product personalization,” RAND Journal of Economics, forthcoming. [17] Fudenberg, D., JM. Villas-Boas (2006): Chapter 7: Behavior-based price discrimination and customer recognition. Handbook of Economics and Information Systems, 1, 377–436. [18] Goldberg, S., G. Johnson, S. Shriver (2024): “Regulating privacy online: An economic evaluation of the GDPR,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy. 16(1): 325-358. [19] Goldfarb A., C. Tucker (2019): “Digital economics,” Journal of Economic Literature. 57(1): 3-43. [20] Ichihashi S. (2020): “Online privacy and information disclosure by consumers,” American Economic Review. 110(2): 569-595. [21] Ichihashi S. (2021): “Competing data intermediaries,” RAND Journal of Economics. 52(3): 515-537. [22] Ke T., K. Sudhir (2023): “Privacy rights and data security: GDPR and personal data driven markets,”Management Science. 69(8): 4389-4412. [23] Lagerlof JNM (2023): “Surfing incognito: Welfare e ¨ ffects of anonymous shopping,” International Journal of Industrial Organization. 87: 102917. [24] Li J, W. Zhang (2025): “Behavior-based pricing and signaling of product quality,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy. 34(1): 139-173. [25] Lin, T. (2022): “Valuing intrinsic and instrumental preferences for privacy,” Marketing Science. 41(4): 663-681. [26] Norberg, P.A., D.R. Horne, D.A. Horne (2007): “The privacy paradox: Personal information disclosure intentions versus behaviors,” Journal of Consumer Affairs. 41(1): 100-126. [27] Rhodes, A., J. Zhou (2024a): “Personalized pricing and competition, ” American Economic Review. 114(7): 2141-2170. [28] Rhodes, A., J. Zhou (2024b): “Personalization and privacy choice, ” Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper. No. 2388. [29] Skreta, V. (2006): “Sequentially optimal mechanisms,” Review of Economic Studies. 73: 1085–1111. [30] Tamir DI, JP. Mitchell (2012): “Disclosing information about the self is intrinsically rewarding,”PNAS. 109(21): 8038-8043. [31] Taylor C R. (2004): “Consumer privacy and the market for customer information,” RAND Journal of Economics. 35(4): 631-650. [32] Villas-Boas J M. (1999): “Dynamic competition with customer recognition, ” RAND Journal of Economics. 30(4): 604-631. [33] Villas-Boas J M. (2004): “Price cycles in markets with customer recognition, ” RAND Journal of Economics. 35(3): 486-501. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/125628 |
Available Versions of this Item
-
The Value of Anonymous Option. (deposited 18 Mar 2025 07:28)
- The Value of Anonymous Option. (deposited 12 Aug 2025 12:57) [Currently Displayed]