Taskin, Temel (2011): Unemployment insurance and home production.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_34878.pdf Download (204kB) | Preview |
Abstract
In this paper, we incorporate home production into a quantitative model of unemployment and show that realistic levels of home production have a significant impact on the optimal unemployment insurance rate. Motivated by recently documented empirical facts, we augment an incomplete markets model of unemployment with a home production technology, which allows unemployed workers to use their extra non-market time as partial insurance against the drop in income due to unemployment. In the benchmark model, we find that the optimal replacement rate in the presence of home production is roughly 40% of wages, which is 40% lower than the no home production model’s optimal replacement rate of 65%. The 40% optimal rate is also close to the estimated rate in practice. The fact that home production makes a significant difference in the optimal unemployment insurance rate is robust to a variety of parameterizations and alternative model environments.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Unemployment insurance and home production |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Unemployment insurance, home production, incomplete markets, self-insurance |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D1 - Household Behavior and Family Economics > D13 - Household Production and Intrahousehold Allocation J - Labor and Demographic Economics > J6 - Mobility, Unemployment, Vacancies, and Immigrant Workers > J65 - Unemployment Insurance ; Severance Pay ; Plant Closings E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy > E21 - Consumption ; Saving ; Wealth |
Item ID: | 34878 |
Depositing User: | Temel Taskin |
Date Deposited: | 08 Dec 2011 18:37 |
Last Modified: | 27 Sep 2019 05:25 |
References: | [1] Abdulkadiroglu, Atila, Burhanettin Kuruscu, and Aysegul Sahin (2002). “Unemployment Insurance and the Role of Self-Insurance,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 5(3), 681-703. [2] Acemoglu, Daron and Robert Shimer (1999), “Efficient Unemployment Insurance,” Journal of Political Economy, 107(5), 893-928. [3] Acemoglu, Daron and Robert Shimer (2000), “Productivity Gains from Unemployment Insurance,” European Economic Review, 44(7), 1195-1224. [4] Aguiar, Mark and Erik Hurst (2005), “Consumption vs. Expenditure,” Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), 919-948. [5] Aguiar, Mark and Erik Hurst (2007), “Life-Cycle Prices and Production,” American Economic Review, 97(5), 1533-1559. [6] Aguiar, Mark and Erik Hurst (2009). “Deconstructing Life-Cycle Expenditure, ”University of Rochester. [7] Aiyagari, S. Rao (1994), “Uninsured Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Saving,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(3), 659-84. [8] ´Alvarez-Parra, Fernando and Juan M. S´anchez (2010), “Unemployment Insurance with a Hidden Labor Market,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(7), pp. 954-67. [9] Bailey, Martin (1978), “Some Aspects of Optimal Unemployment Insurance,” Journal of Public Economics, 10(3), 379-402. [10] Becker, Gary (1965), “A Theory of The Allocation of Time”. The Economic Journal, 75, 493-517. [11] Becker, Gary D. and Gilbert R Ghez (1975), “The Allocation of Time and Goods over the Life Cycle,” NBER. [12] Benhabib, Jess, Richard Rogerson, and Randall Wright (1991), “Homework in Macroeconomics: Household Production and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Journal of Political Economy, 99(6), 1166-87. [13] Browning, Martin and Thomas Crossley (2001), Unemployment Insurance Benefit Levels and Consumption Changes,” Journal of Public Economics, 80(1), 1-23. [14] Burda, Michael C. and Daniel Hamermesh (2010), “Unemployment, Market Work and Individual Production,” Economics Letters, 107(2), 131-33. [15] Canova, Fabio and Angel Ubide (1998), “International Business Cycles, Financial Markets, and Household Production,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 22(4), 545-572. [16] Carroll, Christopher, Karen Dynan, and Spencer Krane (2003), “Unemployment Risk and Precautionary Wealth: Evidence From Households’ Balance Sheets,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(3), 586-604. [17] Chang, Yongsung (2000), “Comovement, Excess Volatility, and Home Production,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 46(2), 385-396. [18] Chang, Yongsung and Andreas Hornstein (2007), “Home Production,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, working paper. [19] Chetty, Raj (2008), “Moral Hazard vs. Liquidity and Optimal Unemployment Insurance,” Journal of Political Economy, 116(2), 173-234. [20] Clark, Kim B. and Lawrence H. Summers (1982), “Unemployment Insurance and Labor Market Transitions,” In Workers, Jobs, and Inflation, edited by Martin Neil Baily. Washington: Brookings Inst. [21] Davidson, Carl and Stephen Woodbury (1997), “Optimal Unemployment Insurance,” Journal of Public Economics, 64(3), 359-387. [22] Engen Eric and Jonathan Gruber (2001), “Unemployment Insurance and Precautionary Saving,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 47(3), 545-579. [23] Flemming, J. S. (1978), “Aspects of Optimal Unemployment Insurance,” Journal of Public Economics, 10(3), 403-425. [24] Greenwood, Jeremy and Zvi Hercowitz (1991), “The Allocation of Capital and Time over the Business Cycle,” Journal of Political Economy, 99(6), 1188-214. [25] Gruber, Jonathan (1997), “The Consumption Smoothing Benefits of Unemployment Insurance,” The American Economic Review, 87(1), 192-205. [26] Gruber, Jonathan (2001), “The Wealth of Unemployed,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 55(1), 79-94. [27] Hagedorn, Marcus, Ashok Kaul and Tim Mennel (2005), “An Adverse Selection Model of Optimal Unemployment Insurance,” mimeo, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics. [28] Hamermesh, Daniel S., Harley Frazis and Jay Stewart, 2005. “Data Watch: The American Time Use Survey,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, American Economic Association, 19(1), 221-232. [29] Hansen, Gary and Ay¸se ˙ Imrohoro˘glu (1992), “The Role of Unemployment Insurance in an Economy with Liquidity Constraints and Moral Hazard,” Journal of Political Economy, 100(1), 118-42. [30] Heathcote, Jonathan, Kjetil Storesletten and Giovanni Violante (2009), “Quantitative Macroeconomics with Heterogeneous Households,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Staff Report. [31] Hopenhayn, Hugo A. and Juan Pablo Nicolini (1997), “Optimal Unemployment Insurance,” Journal of Political Economy, 105(2), 412-38. [32] Jacobs, Kris (2007), “Consumption-Leisure Non-separabilities in Asset Market Participants’ Preferences,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(7), 2131-2138. [33] Kocherlakota, Narayana R.,“Figuring out the impact of hidden savings on optimal unemployment insurance,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 2004, 7 (3), 541554. [34] Krueger, Alan B. and Andreas Mueller (2008), “Job Search and Unemployment Insurance: New Evidence from Time Use Data,” working paper, Industrial Relations Section, Princeton University. [35] Kydland, Finn and Edward Prescott (1991), “Hours and Employment in Business Cycle Theory,” Economic Theory, 1(1), 63-81. [36] Landais, Camille, Pascal Michaillat and Emmanuel Saez (2010), “Optimal Unemployment Insurance over the Business Cycle,” working paper, NBER. [37] Pallage, Stephane and Christian Zimmermann (2005), “Heterogeneous Labor Markets and Generosity Towards Unemployed: An International Perspective,” Journal of Comparative Economics, 33(1), 88-106. [38] Shavell, Steven and Laurence Weiss (1979), “The Optimal Payment of Unemployment Insurance over Time,” Journal of Political Economy, 87(6), 1347-62. [39] Shimer, Robert and Ivan Werning (2008), “Liquidity and Insurance for the Unemployed,” American Economic Review, 98(5), 1922-42. [40] Wang, Cheng and Stephen D. Williamson, “Moral Hazard, Optimal Unemployment Insurance, and Experience Rating,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 2002, 49 (7), 1337-71. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/34878 |