Breitmoser, Yves and Tan, Jonathan H.W. (2014): Reference Dependent Altruism.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_52774.pdf Download (294kB) | Preview |
Abstract
In view of behavioral patterns left unorganized by current social preference theories, we propose a theory of reference dependent altruism (RDA). With RDA, one's degree of altruism increases at reference points. It induces equity and efficiency effects that are conditional on whether or not payoffs meet reference points. We verify the theory first by experimentally analyzing majority bargaining, where observed behavior contradicts existing theories but confirms RDA. Using parameter estimates from majority bargaining, we then make out-of-sample predictions for Charness-Rabin, Engelmann-Strobel, and Bolton-Ockenfels games. RDA organizes these seemingly disparate games out-of-sample, which validates our hypothesis that pro-social behavior primarily relates to reference points.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Reference Dependent Altruism |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | bargaining, non-cooperative game, laboratory experiment, social preferences, quantal response equilibrium |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory > C72 - Noncooperative Games C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory > C78 - Bargaining Theory ; Matching Theory D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D72 - Political Processes: Rent-Seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior |
Item ID: | 52774 |
Depositing User: | Yves Breitmoser |
Date Deposited: | 07 Jan 2014 16:17 |
Last Modified: | 28 Sep 2019 18:34 |
References: | Amemiya, T. (1978). On a two-step estimation of a multivariate logit model. Journal of Econometrics, 8(1):13-21. Andreoni, J. and Bernheim, B. (2009). Social image and the 50-50 norm: A theoretical and experimental analysis of audience effects. Econometrica, 77(5):1607-1636. Andreoni, J. and Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2):737-753. Andreoni, J. and Sprenger, C. (2012a). Estimating time preferences from convex budgets. American Economic Review, 102(7):3333-56. Andreoni, J. and Sprenger, C. (2012b). Risk preferences are not time preferences. American Economic Review, 102(7):3357-76. Ansolabehere, S., Snyder Jr, J., and Ting, M. (2003). Bargaining in bicameral legislatures: When and why does malapportionment matter? American Political Science Review, 97(3):471-481. Arcidiacono, P. and Jones, J. (2003). Finite mixture distributions, sequential likelihood and the em algorithm. Econometrica, 71(3):933-946. Auger, A., Hansen, N., Perez Zerpa, J., Ros, R., and Schoenauer, M. (2009). Experimental comparisons of derivative free optimization algorithms. Experimental Algorithms, pages 3-15. Baron, D. and Ferejohn, J. (1989). Bargaining in legislatures. American Political Science Review, 83(4):1181-1206. Baron, D. and Kalai, E. (1993). The simplest equilibrium of a majority rule division game. Journal of Economic Theory, 61(2):290-301. Battaglini, M. and Palfrey, T. (2012). The dynamics of distributive politics. Economic theory, 49(3):739-77. Bicchieri, C. and Chavez, A. (2010). Behaving as expected: Public information and fairness norms. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 23(2):161-178. Biernacki, C., Celeux, G., and Govaert, G. (1999). An improvement of the nec criterion for assessing the number of clusters in a mixture model. Pattern Recognition Letters, 20(3):267-272. Biernacki, C., Celeux, G., and Govaert, G. (2000). Assessing a mixture model for clustering with the integrated completed likelihood. Pattern Analysis and Machine Intelligence, IEEE Transactions, 22(7):719-725. Blanco, M., Engelmann, D., and Normann, H. T. (2011). A within-subject analysis of other-regarding preferences. Games and Economic Behavior, 72(2):321-338. Bolton, G. and Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90(1):166-193. Bolton, G. E. and Ockenfels, A. (2006). Inequality aversion, efficiency, and maximin preferences in simple distribution experiments: comment. The American economic review, 96(5):1906-1911. Breitmoser, Y., Tan, J., and Zizzo, D. (2010). Understanding perpetual R&D races. Economic Theory, 44(3):445-467. Breitmoser, Y. and Tan, J. H. (2013). Reference dependent altruism in demand bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 92:127-140. Camerer, C. and Thaler, R. (1995). Anomalies: Ultimatums, dictators and manners. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, pages 209-219. Cappelen, A., Hole, A., Sorensen, E., and Tungodden, B. (2007). The pluralism of fairness ideals: An experimental approach. American Economic Review, 97(3):818-827. Cardona, D. and Ponsati, C. (2007). Bargaining one-dimensional social choices. Journal of Economic Theory, 137(1):627-651. Charness, G. and Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3):817-869. Cherry, T., Frykblom, P., and Shogren, J. (2002). Hardnose the dictator. American Economic Review, 92(4):1218-1221. Cho, S. and Duggan, J. (2003). Uniqueness of stationary equilibria in a one-dimensional model of bargaining. Journal of Economic Theory, 113(1):118-130. Cooper, D. J. and Dutcher, E. G. (2011). The dynamics of responder behavior in ultimatum games: a meta-study. Experimental Economics, 14(4):519-546. Cox, J., Friedman, D., and Gjerstad, S. (2007). A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games and Economic Behavior, 59(1):17-45. Diecidue, E. and Van de Ven, J. (2008). Aspiration level, probability of success and failure, and expected utility. International Economic Review, 49(2):683-700. Diermeier, D., Eraslan, H., and Merlo, A. (2002). Coalition governments and comparative constitutional design. European Economic Review, 46(4-5):893-907. Diermeier, D., Eraslan, H., and Merlo, A. (2003). A structural model of government formation. Econometrica, 71(1):27-70. Drouvelis, M., Montero, M., and Sefton, M. (2010). Gaining power through enlargement: Strategic foundations and experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 69(2):274-292. Engelmann, D. and Strobel, M. (2004). Inequality aversion, efficiency, and maximin preferences in simple distribution experiments. American Economic Review, 94(4):857-869. Engelmann, D. and Strobel, M. (2006). Inequality aversion, efficiency, and maximin preferences in simple distribution experiments: Reply. The American economic review, 96(5):1918-1923. Eraslan, H. (2002). Uniqueness of stationary equilibrium payoffs in the baron-ferejohn model. Journal of Economic Theory, 103(1):11-30. Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3):817-868. Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. (2010). On inequity aversion: a reply to binmore and shaked. Journal of economic behavior & organization, 73(1):101-108. Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2):171-178. Frechette, G., Kagel, J., and Morelli, M. (2005a). Behavioral identification in coalitional bargaining: An experimental analysis of demand bargaining and alternating offers. Econometrica, 73(6):1893-1937. Frechette, G., Kagel, J., and Morelli, M. (2005b). Nominal bargaining power, selection protocol, and discounting in legislative bargaining. Journal of Public Economics, 89(8):1497-1517. Frechette, G., Kagel, J., and Morelli, M. (2012). Pork versus public goods: an experimental study of public good provision within a legislative bargaining framework. Economic Theory, 49:779-800. Gneiting, T. and Raferty, A. (2007). Strictly proper scoring rules, prediction, and estimation. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 102(477):359-378. Goeree, J., Holt, C., and Laury, S. (2002). Private costs and public benefits: unraveling the effects of altruism and noisy behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 83(2):255-276. Jackson, M. and Moselle, B. (2002). Coalition and party formation in a legislative voting game. Journal of Economic Theory, 103(1):49-87. Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2):263-291. Knez, M. and Camerer, C. (1995). Outside options and social comparison in three-player ultimatum game experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1):65-94. Knight, B. (2005). Estimating the value of proposal power. American Economic Review, 95(5):1639-1652. Koszegi, B. and Rabin, M. (2006). A model of reference-dependent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4):1133-1165. Koszegi, B. and Rabin, M. (2007). Reference-dependent risk attitudes. American Economic Review, 97(4):1047-1073. Kritikos, A. and Bolle, F. (2001). Distributional concerns: equity- or efficiency-oriented? Economics Letters, 73(3):333-338. McFadden, D. (1978). Modelling the choice of residential location. In Karlqvist, A., Lundqvist, L., Snickars, F., and Weibull, J., editors, Spatial interaction theory and planning models, pages 75-96. North Holland, Amsterdam. McFadden, D. (1984). Econometric analysis of qualitative response models. Handbook of econometrics, 2:1395-1457. McKelvey, R. and Palfrey, T. (1995). Quantal response equilibria for normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1):6-38. McKelvey, R. and Palfrey, T. (1998). Quantal response equilibria for extensive form games. Experimental Economics, 1(1):9-41. McLachlan, G. and Peel, D. (2000). Finite mixture models, volume 299. Wiley-Interscience. Montero, M. (2006). Noncooperative foundations of the nucleolus in majority games. Games and Economic Behavior, 54(2):380-397. Montero, M. (2007). Inequity aversion may increase inequity. The Economic Journal, 117(519):192-204. Montero, M., Sefton, M., and Zhang, P. (2008). Enlargement and the balance of power: an experimental study. Social Choice and Welfare, 30(1):69-87. More, J. and Wild, S. (2009). Benchmarking derivative-free optimization algorithms. SIAM Journal on Optimization, 20(1):172-191. Murnighan, J., Roth, A., and Schoumaker, F. (1988). Risk aversion in bargaining: An experimental study. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1(1):101-124. Neilson, W. (2006). Axiomatic reference-dependence in behavior toward others and toward risk. Economic Theory, 28(3):681-692. Okada, A. (2011). Coalitional bargaining games with random proposers: Theory and application. Games and Economic Behavior, 73(1):227 - 235. Powell, M. (2008). Developments of newuoa for minimization without derivatives. IMA journal of numerical analysis, 28(4):649. Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. American Economic Review, 83(5):1281-1302. Schwarz, G. (1978). Estimating the dimension of a model. Annals of Statistics, 6(2):461-464. Selten, R. (1998). Axiomatic characterization of the quadratic scoring rule. Experimental Economics, 1(1):43-62. Shalev, J. (2002). Loss aversion and bargaining. Theory and Decision, 52(3):201-232. Snyder Jr, J., Ting, M., and Ansolabehere, S. (2005). Legislative bargaining under weighted voting. American Economic Review, 95(4):981-1004. Stahl, D. and Wilson, P. (1995). On players' models of other players: Theory and experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1):218-254. Thaler, R. (1988). Anomalies: The ultimatum game. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2(4):195-206. Vuong, Q. (1989). Likelihood ratio tests for model selection and non-nested hypotheses. Econometrica, 57(2):307-333. Yildirim, H. (2007). Proposal power and majority rule in multilateral bargaining with costly recognition. Journal of Economic Theory, 136(1):167-196. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/52774 |