Dotti, Valerio (2014): The Political Economy of Publicly Provided Private Goods.

Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_54026.pdf Download (410kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Abstract Traditional Political Economy models typically imply a strong relationship between income inequality and public intervention in redistributive policies. Empirical evidence suggests that this may hold true only for certain kinds of policies, for instance cash transfers or education, but in the case of other policies with redistributive effects such as social security and some publicly provided private goods this may not hold true.
Abstract In this paper I develop a method to derive the sign of the relationship between income inequality and degree of public intervention in education in a Probabilistic Voting model in which the consumers-voters are also allowed to choose other forms of redistribution.
Abstract I show that the relationship between income inequality and governmental intervention implied in the traditional literature is mainly a result of the restrictive assumptions of those models.
Abstract I also show that this method can deliver sharp predictions even in presence of those non-convexities in individual preferences that are usually described as a feature induced by public provision of education in the traditional literature in Public Economics.
Abstract I argue that the relationship between income inequality and public intervention in schooling is a natural and promising field in which the tool proposed can be useful for empirical purposes and that can help to better explain some patterns described in the literature about public intervention in education.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | The Political Economy of Publicly Provided Private Goods |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Keywords: Political Economy; Probabilistic models; public provision; income inequality |
Subjects: | H - Public Economics > H4 - Publicly Provided Goods > H44 - Publicly Provided Goods: Mixed Markets H - Public Economics > H5 - National Government Expenditures and Related Policies > H52 - Government Expenditures and Education |
Item ID: | 54026 |
Depositing User: | Mr Valerio Dotti |
Date Deposited: | 02 Mar 2014 16:55 |
Last Modified: | 08 Oct 2019 04:41 |
References: | Aranson, P., Hinich, M., and Ordeshook, P. (1974). “Election goals and strategies: Equivalent and nonequivalent candidate objectives”, American Political Science Review 68: 135-152. Bassett, W.F., Burkett, J.P., Putterman, L. (1999), “Income distribution, government transfers, and the problem of unequal influence”, European Journal of Political Economy Vol. 15 1999 207–228. Banks, J.S., and J. Duggan (2005). "Probabilistic Voting in the Spatial Model of Elec-tions: The Theory of Office-Motivated Candidates". In Social Choice and Strategic Decisions: Essays in Honor of Jeffrey S. Banks, ed. David Austen-Smith and John Duggan, 15-56. New York: Springer. Becker, G.S., Tomes, N. (1986). “Human Capital and the Rise and Fall of Families”. Journal of Labor Economics, University of Chicago Press, vol. 4(3), pages S1-39, July. Besley, T., Coate, S. (1991). “Public provision of private goods and the redistribution of income,” American Economic Review, 81, 979–984. Besley, T., Coate, S. (1997). “An Economic Model of Representative Democracy”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(1), 85-114, 1997. Black, D. (1948). “On the Rationale of Group Decisionmaking”, Journal of Political Economy, 56: 23-34. De Mello, L. and Tiongson, E.R. (2006), “Income Inequality and Redistributive Government Spending”, Public Finance Review, 34, 282-305. Downs, A. (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper Collins. Enelow, J.M., Hinich, M.J. (1989). “A general probabilistic spatial theory of elections”, Publ& Choice 61: 101-113. Epple, D., Romano, R.E. (1996). “Public provision of private goods”, Journal of Political Economy, 104, 57–84. Epple, D. and Romano, R.E. (1996), “Ends against the middle: Determining public service provision when there are private alternatives”, Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier, vol. 62(3), pages 297-325, November. Easterly, W. and Rebelo, S. (1993). "Fiscal policy and economic growth: An empirical investigation," Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, vol. 32(3), pages 417-458, December. Gouveia, M. (1997). “Majority rule and the public provision of health care”, Public Choice, 93, 221–244. Grandmont, J.-M. (1978). “Intermediate preferences and the majority rule”, Econometrica, 46, 317–330. Levy, G. (2005). “The Politics of Public Provision of Education”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 120, No. 4, pp. 1507-1534 Lindbeck A., Weibull, J.W. (1987). “Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition”, Public Choice, 52, Number 3, 273-297. Plott, C. R. (1967). A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule. American Economic Review 57 (Sept.): 787-806. Roemer, J.E. (1999). “The Democratic Political Economy of Progressive Taxation”, Econometrica, 67, 1-19. Sylwester (2000). “Income inequality, education expenditures, and growth”, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 63, 379–398. Sylwester, K. (2002). “Can education expenditures reduce income inequality?”, Economics of Education Review, 21, 43–52. Stiglitz, J.E. (1974). “The demand for education in public and private school systems”, Journal of Public Economics, 3, 349–385. 61 Usher, D. (1977). “The welfare economics of the socialization of commodities”, Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier, vol. 8(2), pages 151-168, October. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/54026 |
Available Versions of this Item
- The Political Economy of Publicly Provided Private Goods. (deposited 02 Mar 2014 16:55) [Currently Displayed]