Al-Ubaydli, Omar and McCabe, Kevin and Twieg, Peter (2014): Can more be less? An experimental test of the resource curse.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_55381.pdf Download (778kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Several scholars have argued that abundant natural resources can be harmful to economic performance under bad institutions and helpful when institutions are good. These arguments have either been theoretical or based on naturally-occurring variation in natural resource wealth. We test this theory using a laboratory experiment to reap the benefits of randomized control. We conduct this experiment in a virtual world (Second LifeTM) to make institutions more visceral. We find support for the theory.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Can more be less? An experimental test of the resource curse |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | resource curse; institutions; economic development |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D72 - Political Processes: Rent-Seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D74 - Conflict ; Conflict Resolution ; Alliances ; Revolutions O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O1 - Economic Development > O13 - Agriculture ; Natural Resources ; Energy ; Environment ; Other Primary Products Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics ; Environmental and Ecological Economics > Q3 - Nonrenewable Resources and Conservation > Q34 - Natural Resources and Domestic and International Conflicts |
Item ID: | 55381 |
Depositing User: | Omar Al-Ubaydli |
Date Deposited: | 21 Apr 2014 12:15 |
Last Modified: | 29 Sep 2019 12:08 |
References: | Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson and J. Robinson (2001). “The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation,” American Economic Review, 91, p1369-1401. Acemoglu, D. and J. Robinson (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Acemoglu, D., T. Verdier and J. Robinson (2004). “Kleptocracy and divide-and-rule: a model of personal rule,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, p162-192. Alexeev, M. and R. Conrad (2009). “The elusive curse of oil,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 91, p586-598. Al-Ubaydli, O. (2011). “Natural resources and the tradeoff between authoritarianism and development,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, forthcoming. Andersen, S. and J. Aslaksen (2008). “Constitutions and the resource curse,” Journal of Development Economics, 87, p227-246. Atlas, S. and L. Putterman (2011). “Trust among the avatars: A virtual world experiment, with and without textual and visual cues,” Southern Economic Journal, forthcoming. Auty, R. (2001). Resource abundance and economic development. World Institute for Development Economics Research, Oxford University Press. Banerjee, A. and E. Duflo (2009). “The experimental approach to development economics,” Annual Review of Economics, 1, p151-178. Bateson, M., D. Nettle, and G. Roberts (2006). “Cues of being watched enhance cooperation in a real-world setting,” Biology Letters, 2, p412-414. Baye, M., D. Kovenock and C. De Vries (1994). “The solution to the Tullock rent-seeking game when R > 2: Mixed-strategy equilibria and mean dissipation rates,” Public Choice, 81, p363-380. Bente, G., S. Rüggenberg, N. Krämer and F. Eschenburg (2008). “Avatar-mediated networking: Increasing social presence and interpersonal trust in net-based collaborations,” Human Communication Research, 34, p287–318. Blume, A. and A. Ortmann (2007). “The effects of costless pre-play communication: experimental evidence from games with Pareto-ranked equilibria,” Journal of Economic Theory, 132, p274-290. Brandts, J. and D. Cooper (2005). “It’s what you say not what you play,” Working paper, Case Western University. Bulte, E. and R. Damania (2008). “Resources for sale: Corruption, democracy and the natural resource curse,” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 8, article 5. Burton, A. and M. Sefton (2001). “Risk, pre-play communication and equilibrium,” Games and Economic Behavior, 46, p23-40. Charness, G. and U. Gneezy (2008). “What's in a name? Anonymity and social distance in dictator and ultimatum games,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 68, p29-35. Charness, G. and B. Grosskopf (2004). “What makes cheap talk effective? Experimental evidence,” Economics Letters, 83, p383-389. Charness, G., E. Haruvy, and D. Sonsino (2007),“Social Distance and Reciprocity: An Internet Experiment,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 63, p88-103. Chesney, T., S. Chuah and R. Hoffmann (2009). “Virtual world experimentation: An exploratory study,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 72, p618-635. Compton, R., D. Giedeman and N. Johnson (2010). “Investing in institutions,” Economics and Politics, 22, p419-445. Cooper, R., D. DeJong, R. Forsythe and T. Ross (1992). “Communication in coordination games,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, p. 739-771. Duffy, J. and N. Feltovich (2002). “Do actions speak louder than words? An experimental comparison of observation and cheap talk,” Games and Economic Behavior. 39, p1-27. Engerman, S. and K. Sokoloff (1997). “Factor endowments, institutions and deifferential paths of growth among New World economies,” in S. Haber (ed) How Latin America Fell Behind, Stanford University Press, Stanford CA. Durlauf, S. and M. Fafchamps (2004). “Social capital,” working paper, University of Wisconsin at Maddison. Fielder, M., E. Haruvy and S. Li (2011). “Social distance in a virtual world experiment,” Games and Economic Behavior, forthcoming. Frenkel, J. (2010). “The natural resource curse: A survey,” NBER working paper 15863. Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Hodler, R. (2006). “The curse of natural resources in fractionalized countries,” European Economic Review, 50, p1367-1386. Kang, S., J. Watt and S. Ala (2008). “Communicators’ perceptions of social presence as a function of avatar realism in small display mobile communication devices,” Proceedings of the 41st Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences, Washington, DC: IEEE Computer Society, p1–10. Kimbrough, E., V. Smith and B. Wilson (2008). “Historical property rights, sociality, and the emergence of interpersonal exchange in long-distance trade,” American Economic Review, 98, p1009-1039. Knapp, G. and J. Murphy (2010). “Voluntary approaches to transitioning from competitive fisheries to rights-based management: Bringing the field into the lab,” Agricultural and Resource Economics Review, 39, p245-261. Lakin, J., V. Jefferis, C. Cheng and T. Chartrand (2003). “The chameleon effect as social glue: evidence for the evolutionary significance of nonconscious mimicry,” Journal of Nonverbal Behavior, 27, p145-162. Leibbrandt, A. and J. Lynham (2013). “Does the resource curse exist? An experimental test,” Working paper, Monash University. McCabe, K., P. Twieg and J. Weel (2011). “Investigating the endogenous emergence of social networks and trade: A virtual worlds experiment,” working paper, George Mason University. Mehlum, H., K. Moene and R. Torvik (2006). “Institutions and the resource curse,” Economic Journal, 116, p1-20. Morgan, J. and M. Sefton (2000). “Funding public goods with lotteries: Experimental evidence,” Review of Economic Studies, 67, p785-810. North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. New York, USA: Cambridge University Press. North, D., J. Wallis and B. Weingast (2009). Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Nowak, K, J. Watt and J. Walther (2005). “The influence of synchrony and sensory modality on the person perception process in computer-mediated groups,” Journal of Computer-Mediated Communication, 10, article 3. Nti, K. (1997). “Comparative statics of contests and rent-seeking games,” International Economic Review, 38, p43-59. Olsson, O. (2006). “Diamonds are a rebel’s best friend,” World Economy, 29, p1133-1150. Olsson, O. (2007). “Conflict diamonds,” Journal of Development Economics, 82, p267-286. Ostrom, E., J. Walker and R. Gardner (1992). “Covenants with and without a sword: Self-governance is possible,” American Political Science Review, 86, p404-417. Ostrom, E. (2000). “Collective action and the evolution of social norms,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14, p137-158. Potters, J., C. de Vries and F. van Winden (1998). “An experimental examination of rational rent-seeking,” European Journal of Political Economy, p783-800. Robinson, J., R. Torvik and T. Verdier (2005). “Political foundations of the resource curse,” Journal of Development Economics, 79, p447-468. Ross, M. (2001). “Does oil hinder democracy?,” World Politics, 53, p325-361. Sachs, J. and A. Warner (1995). “Natural resource abundance and economic growth,” NBER Working Paper 5398. Torvik, R. (2002). “Natural resources, rent-seeking and welfare.” Journal of Development Economics, 67, p455-470. Tullock, G. (1980). “Efficient rent seeking,” in J. Buchanan, R. Tollison and G. Tullock (eds), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (College Station: Texas A&M University Press), p97-112. Tsui, K. (2009). “More oil, less democracy? Theory and evidence from crude oil discoveries,” Economic Journal, forthcoming. Vicente, P. (2010). “Does oil corrupt? Evidence from a natural experiment in West Africa,” Journal of Development Economics, 92, p28-38. Walker, J., R. Gardner and E. Ostrom (1990). “Rent dissipation in a limited-access common-pool resource: Experimental evidence,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 19, p203-211. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/55381 |