Bethencourt, Carlos and Kunze, Lars (2014): On the intergenerational nature of criminal behavior.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_58344.pdf Download (345kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Empirical evidence suggests that family background and parental criminality are strong predictors of an individuals’ criminal behavior. The aim of this paper is to account for this intergenerational nature of criminal behavior within a simple theoretical model. Drawing on the literature of cultural transmission, we model the dynamics of moral norms of good conduct (honest behavior). Individuals’ criminal behavior and morality are strategic complementarities that reinforce each other. We establish the existence of multiple steady states and provide conditions on the socialization process under which both types - honest and dishonest - survive in the long run even though parents commit crime but at the same time agree that honesty is desirable. Our model provides a novel explanation of why crime is highly concentrated in specific areas and also why crime rates tend to be persistent over time. An empirical application reveals that our model can account for the differential reductions in property crime rates across US federal states since the 1980s.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | On the intergenerational nature of criminal behavior |
English Title: | On the intergenerational nature of criminal behavior |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | crime, cultural transmission |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D9 - Intertemporal Choice > D91 - Intertemporal Household Choice ; Life Cycle Models and Saving H - Public Economics > H2 - Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue > H26 - Tax Evasion and Avoidance Z - Other Special Topics > Z1 - Cultural Economics ; Economic Sociology ; Economic Anthropology > Z13 - Economic Sociology ; Economic Anthropology ; Social and Economic Stratification |
Item ID: | 58344 |
Depositing User: | Carlos Bethencourt |
Date Deposited: | 06 Sep 2014 10:14 |
Last Modified: | 27 Sep 2019 09:05 |
References: | Anderson, D., 2014. In school and out of trouble? The minimum dropout age and juvenile crime. Review of Economics and Statistics 96, 318–331. Andreoni, J., 1990. Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. The Economic Journal 100, 464–477. Ballester, C., Calvo-Armengol, A., Zenou, Y., 2006. Who’s who in networks. wanted: the key player. Econometrica 74, 1403–1417. Ballester, C., Calvo-Armengol, A., Zenou, Y., 2010. Delinquent networks. Journal of the European Economic Association 8, 34–61. Bayer, P., Hjalmarsson, R., Pozen, D., 2009. Building criminal capital behind bars: Peer effects in juvenile corrections. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124, 105–147. Becker, G., 1968. Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy 76, 169–217. Bethencourt, C., 2014. Crime and social expenditure: A political economic approach. Mimeo. Bisin, A., Verdier, T., 2000. Beyond the melting pot: Cultural transmission, marriage and the evolution of ethnic and religous traits. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115, 955–988. Bisin, A., Verdier, T., 2001. The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences. Journal of Economic Theory 97, 298–319. Bisin, A., Verdier, T., 2011. The economics of cultural transmission and socialization. Handbook of Social Economics 1A, ch.9. Block, M. K., Heineke, J. M., 1975. A labor theoretic analysis of criminal choice. American Economic Review 65, 314–325. Boyd, R., Richerson, P. J., 1985. Culture and the Evolutionary Process. University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Brush, J., 2007. Does income inequality lead to more crime? A comparison of cross-sectional and time-series analyses of United States counties. Economics Letters 96, 264–268. Calvo-Armengol, A., Verdier, T., Zenou, Y., 2007. Strong and weak ties in employment and crime. Journal of Public Economics 91, 203–233. Calvo-Armengol, A., Zenou, Y., 2004. Social networks and crime decisions: The role of social structure in facilitating delinquent behavior. International Ecomic Review 45, 935–954. Cavalli-Sforza, L., Feldman, M., 1981. Cultural Transmission and Evolution. A Quantitative Approach. Princeton University Press, Princeton. Chintrakarn, P., Herzer, D., 2012. More inequality, more crime? A panel cointegration analysis for the United States. Economics Letters 116, 389–391. Chiu, W. H., Madden, P., 1998. Burglary and income inequality. Journal of Public Economics 69, 123–141. Conley, J., Wang, P., 2006. Crime and ethics. Journal of Urban Economics 60, 107–123. Damm, A. P., Dustmann, C., 2014. Does growing up in a high crime neighborhood affect youth criminal behavior? American Economic Review 104, 1806–1832. Deming, D., 2011. Better schools, less crime? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126, 2063–2115. Demombynes, G., Oezler, B., 2005. Crime and local inequality in South Africa. Journal of Development Economics 76, 265–292. Di Tella, R., Schargrodsky, E., 2004. Do police reduce crime? estimates using the allocation of police forces after a terrorist attack. American Economic Review 94, 115–133. Draca, M., Machin, S., Witt, R., 2011. Panic on the streets of london: police, crime and the july 2005 terror attacks. American Economic Review 101, 2157–2181. Duncan, G., Kalil, A., Mayer, S. E., Tepper, R., Payne, M. R., 2005. The apple does not fall far from the tree. Russel Sage Foundation. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Engelhardt, B., Rocheteau, G., Rupert, P., 2008. Crime and the labor market: a search model with optimal contracts. Journal of Public Economics 92, 1876–1891. Eriksson, K. H., Hjalmarsson, R., Lindquist, M., Sandberg, A., 2014. The importance of family background and neighborhood effects as determinants of crime. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 9911. Frank, W. M., 2008. A new state-level panel of income inequality measures over the period 1916-2005. SHSU Economics and Int. Business Working Paper no. SHSU-ECO-Wp08-02. Freeman, R. B., 1996. Why do so many young american men commit crime and what might we do about it? Journal of Economic Perspectives 10, 25–42. Freeman, S., Grogger, J., Sonstelie, J., 1996. The spatial concentration of crime. Journal of Urban Economics 40, 216–231. Glaeser, E., Sacerdote, B., Scheinkman, J., 1996. Crime and social interaction. Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, 508–548. Glaeser, E. L., 1998. Are cities dying? Journal of Economic Perspectives 12, 139–160. Glaeser, E. L., Sacerdote, B., 1999. Why is there more crime in cities? Journal of Political Economy 107, 225–258. Glaeser, E. L., Sacerdote, B. I., Scheinkman, J. A., 2003. The social multiplier. Journal of European Economic Association 1, 345–353. Grogger, J., Willis, M., 2000. The emergence of crack cocaine and the rise in urban crime rates. The Review of Economics and Statistics 82, 519–529. Hauk, E., Sáez-Marti, M., 2002. On the cultural transmission of corruption. Journal of Economic Theory 107, 311–335. Hjalmarsson, R., Lindquist, M. J., 2012. Like godfather, like son: Exploring the intergenerational nature of crime. Journal of Human Resources 47, 1–40. Hjalmarsson, R., Lindquist, M. J., 2013. The origins of intergenerational associations in crime: Lessons from swedish adoption data. Labour Economics 20, 68–81. Imrohoroglu, A., Merlo, A., Rupert, P., 2004. What accounts for the decline in crime? International Economic Review 45, 707–729. Imrohoroglu, A., Merlo, A., Rupert, P., 2006. Understanding the determinants of crime. Journal of Economics and Finance 30, 270–283. Kahn, M. E., 2010. New evidence on trends in the cost of urban agglomeration, in: E.l. Glaeser (Ed.). Economics of Agglomeration, Chicago: The University of Chicago University Press, 339–354. Kling, J., Ludwig, J., Katz, L., 2005. Neighborhood effects on crime for female and male youth: Evidence from a randomized housing voucher experiment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, 87–130. Levitt, S. D., 2004. Understanding why crime fell in the 1990: four factors that explain the decline and six that do not. Journal of Economic Perspectives 18, 163–190. Lochner, L., 2004. Education, work and crime: A human capital approach. International Economic Review 45, 811–843. Lochner, L., 2011. Non-production benefits of education: Crime, health, and good citizenship, in E. Hanushek, S. Machin and L. Woessmann, eds. Handbook of the Economics of Education, 183–282. Lochner, L., Moretti, E., 2004. The effect of education on crime: Evidence from prison inmates, arrests, and self-reports. American Economic Review 94, 155–189. Ludwig, J., Duncan, G. J., Hirschfeld, P., 2001. Urban poverty and juvenile crime: Evidence from a randomized housing-mobility experiment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, 655–679. Patacchini, E., Zenou, Y., 2011. Neighborhood effects and parental involvement in the intergenerational transmission of education. The Journal of Regional Science 51, 987–1013. Patacchini, E., Zenou, Y., 2012. Juvenile delinquency and conformism. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 28, doi: 10.1093/jleo/ewp038. Rowe, D., Farrington, D. P., 1997. The familial transmission of criminal convictions. Criminology 35, 177–202. Sah, R., 1991. Social osmosis and patterns of crime. Journal of Political Economy 99, 1272–1295. Sáez-Marti, M., Sjögren, A., 2008. Peers and culture. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 110, 73–92. Sáez-Marti, M., Zenou, Y., 2012. Cultural transmission and discrimination. Journal of Urban Economics 72, 137–146. Tabellini, G., 2008. The scope of cooperation: Values and incentives. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, 905–950. Thornberry, T. P., 2009. The apple doesn’t fall far from the tree (or does it?): Intergenerational patterns of antisocial behaviour - The American Society of Criminology 2008 Sutherland Address. Criminology 47, 297–325. Verdier, T., Zenou, Y., 2004. Radical beliefs, location and the causes of crime. International Economic Review 45, 731–760. Zenou, Y., 2003. The spatial aspects of crime. Journal of the European Economic Association 1, 459–467. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/58344 |