Hattori, Keisuke (2007): Strategic Voting for Noncooperative Environmental Policies in Open Economies.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_6333.pdf Download (136kB) | Preview |
Abstract
In this paper, we construct a political-economy model of international noncooperative environmental policymaking, and examine the strategic incentives for voters to elect an environmental policymaker in open economies. We show that under several circumstances, citizens have an incentive to deliberately vote for a candidate whose environmental preferences differ from their own. Further, the strategic voting incentives are crucially depend on the environmental policy tools employed by the government, the international market structures, and the degree of product differentiation among firms.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Strategic Voting for Noncooperative Environmental Policies in Open Economies |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | strategic voting, the race to the bottom, market structure, environmental policy |
Subjects: | F - International Economics > F1 - Trade > F18 - Trade and Environment D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D72 - Political Processes: Rent-Seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior D - Microeconomics > D4 - Market Structure, Pricing, and Design > D43 - Oligopoly and Other Forms of Market Imperfection |
Item ID: | 6333 |
Depositing User: | Keisuke Hattori |
Date Deposited: | 18 Dec 2007 06:37 |
Last Modified: | 01 Oct 2019 18:32 |
References: | [1] Antweiler, W., Copeland, W., Taylor, M., (2001) “Is Free Trade Good for the Environment?”, American Economic Review 91 (4) 877-908. [2] Barrett, S., (1994) “Strategic Environmental Policy and International Trade”, Journal of Public Economics, 54 (3), 325-338. [3] Besley, T., Coate, S., (2003) Centralized versus Decentralized Provision of Local Public Goods: A Political Economy Approach, Journal of Public Economics, 87, 2611-2637. [4] Buchholz, W. and Konrad, K.A., (1994) “Global Environmental Problems and the Strategic Choice of Technology” Journal of Economics 60 299-321. [5] Buchholz, W., Haupt, A., Peters, W., (2005) International Environmental Agreements and Strategic Voting, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 107, 175-195. [6] Congleton, R.D., (1992) “Political Institutions and Pollution Control”, Review of Economics and Statistics 74 412-421. [7] Congleton, R.D., (1996) The Political Economy of Environmental Protection: Analysis and Evidence, University of Michigan Press. [8] Conrad, K., (1996) “Optimal Environmental Policy for Oligopolistic Industries under Intraindustry trade”, in Carraro, C., Katsoulacos, Y., Xepapadeas, A., Ed., Environmental Policy and Market Structure, Kluwer, Dordrecht, 65-83. [9] Fredriksson, P., (1997) “The Political Economy of Pollution Taxes in a Small Open Economy”, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 33 44-58. [10] Fredriksson, P., (1999) “The Political Economy of Trade Liberalization and Environmental Policy”, Southern Economic Journal 65 513-525. [11] Fredriksson, P., Millimet, D., (2002) “Strategic Interaction and the Determination of Environmental Policy across U.S. States”, Journal of Urban Economics 51 101-122. [12] Hattori, K., (2007) “Strategic Delegation of Environmental Policy Making: Corrections and Comments”, Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1009425. [13] Kennedy, P.W., (1994) “Equilibrium Pollution Taxes in Open Economies with Imperfect Competition”, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 27 49-63. [14] Kreps, D.M., Scheinkman, J.A., (1983) “Quantity Precommitment and Bertrand Competition Yield Cournot Outcomes”, Bel l Journal of Economics 14, 326-337. [15] List, J., Gerking, S., (2000) “Regulatory Federalism and U.S. Environmental Policies”, Journal of Regional Science 40 453-471. [16] Millimet, D.L., (2003) “Assessing the Empirical Impact of Environmental Federalism”, Journal of Regional Science 43, 711-733. [17] Murdoch, J.C. and Sandler, T., (1997) “The Voluntary Provision of a Pure Public Good: The Case of Reduced CFC Emissions and the Montreal Protocol” Journal of Public Economics 63 331-349. [18] Oates, W.E., Portney, P.R., (2003) “The Political Economy of Environmental Policy”, in M ̈aler, K.-G., Vincent, J.R., Ed., Handbook of Environmental Economics, Vol.1, Elsevier Science B.V., 325-354. [19] Rauscher, M., (1997) International Trade, Factor Movements, and the Environment, Clarendon Press, Oxford. [20] Rauscher, M., (2005) “International Trade, Foreign Investment, and the Environment”, in M ̈aler, K.-G., Vincent, J.R., Ed., Handbook of Environmental Economics, Vol.3, Elsevier Science B.V., 1403-1456. [21] Roelfsema, H., (2007) “Strategic Delegation of Environmental Policy Making”, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 53 (2) 270-275. [22] Schleich, J., (1999) “Environmental Policy with Endogenous Domestic Trade Policies”, European Journal of Political Economy 15 53-71. [23] Siqueria, K., (2003) “International Externalities, Strategic Interaction, and Domestic Politics”, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 45 674-691. [24] Ulph, A.M., (1992) “The Choice of Environmental Policy Instruments and Strategic International Trade”, in Pethig, R., Ed., Conflicts and Cooperation in Managing Environmental Resources, Springer Verlag, 111-129. [25] Ulph, A.M., (1996) “Environmental Policy Instruments and Imperfectly Competitive International Trade”, Environmental and Resource Economics 7 333-355. [26] Ulph, A.M., (1998) “Political Institutions and the Design of Environmental Policy in a Federal System with Asymmetric Information”, European Economic Review 42 583-592. [27] World Bank, (2000) “Is Globalization Causing a ‘Race to the Bottom’ in Environmental Stan- dards?”, in Assessing Globalization, World Bank Briefing Papers. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/6333 |