Banerjee, Priyodorshi and Das, Tanmoy (2015): Are Contingent Choices Consistent?
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_66995.pdf Download (269kB) | Preview |
Abstract
A contingent plan is consistent if the specification for any particular contingency in the plan is invariant to the set of alternative contingencies or, equivalently, is independent of irrelevant information emerging from alternative contingencies or choice problems. Our experiments show that consistency may be obtainable when choice problems are complete, with monetary and immediate outcomes, but is likely to face violation in more complex settings. We further found that decisions are more likely to change when irrelevant information arises rather than subsides, and that any observed failure of consistency has the use of irrelevant information in decision-making at its core.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Are Contingent Choices Consistent? |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | contingent plans, consistent choices, irrelevant information and decision making |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C9 - Design of Experiments > C91 - Laboratory, Individual Behavior D - Microeconomics > D0 - General > D01 - Microeconomic Behavior: Underlying Principles D - Microeconomics > D0 - General > D03 - Behavioral Microeconomics: Underlying Principles D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty > D81 - Criteria for Decision-Making under Risk and Uncertainty G - Financial Economics > G1 - General Financial Markets > G11 - Portfolio Choice ; Investment Decisions |
Item ID: | 66995 |
Depositing User: | Tanmoy Das |
Date Deposited: | 01 Oct 2015 04:52 |
Last Modified: | 02 Oct 2019 13:14 |
References: | [1] Bodenhausen, G. and R. Wyer (1985): Effects of Stereotypes on Decision Making and Information-Processing Strategies, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 48, 267-82. [2] Coman, D., A. Coman and W. Hirst (2013): Memory Accessibility and Medical Decision-Making for Significant Others: the Role of Socially Shared Retrieval-Induced Forgetting, Frontiers in Behavioral Neuroscience, 7, article 72. [3] Dror, I., D. Charlton and A. Peron (2006): Contextual Information Renders Experts Vulnerable to Making Erroneous Identifications, Forensic Science International, 156, 74-8. [4] Fabozzi, F., P. Kolm, D. Pachamanova and S. Forcardi (2007): Robust Portfoilio Optimization and Management. Wiley: Hoboken, New Jersey. [5] Green, E. and K. Osband (1991): Revealed Preference Theory for Expected Utility, Review of Economic Studies, 58, 677-95. [6] Green, E. and I. Park (1996): Bayes Contingent Plans, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 31, 225-36. [7] Heston, A., R. Summers and B. Aten (2012): Penn World Table Version 7.1, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices, University of Pennsylvania. [8] Jones, M. and B. Love (2011): Bayesian Fundamentalism or Enlightenment? On the Explanatory Status and Theoretical Contributions of Bayesian Models of Cognition, Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 34, 169-231. [9] Jorgensen, M. and S. Grimstad (2011): The Impact of Irrelevant and Misleading Information on Software Development Effort Estimates: A Randomized Controlled Field Experiment, IEEE Transactions on Software Engineering, 37, 695-707. [10] Rubinstein, A. (2012): Lecture Notes in Microeconomic Theory, 2nd edition. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [11] Sargent, T. (1987): Macroeconomic Theory, 2nd edition. Bingley: Emerald. [12] Savage, L. (1972): The Foundations of Statistics, 2nd edition. New York: Dover. [13] Zambrano, E. (2005): Testable Implications of Subjective Expected Utility Theory, Games and Economic Behavior, 53, 262-68. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/66995 |