Breitmoser, Yves (2016): Stochastic choice, systematic mistakes and preference estimation.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_72779.pdf Download (802kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Individual choice exhibits "presentation effects" such as default, ordering and round-number effects. Using existing models, presentation effects bias utility estimates, which suggests instability of preferences and obscures behavioral patterns. This paper derives a generalized model of stochastic choice by weakening logit's axiomatic foundation. Weakening the axioms implies that focality of options is choice-relevant, alongside utility, which entails presentation effects. The model is tested on four well-known studies of dictator games exhibiting typical round-number patterns. The generalized logit model captures the choice patterns reliably, substantially better than existing models: it robustly predicts and controls for the round-number effects, thus provides "clean" utility estimates that are stable and predictive across experiments.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Stochastic choice, systematic mistakes and preference estimation |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | stochastic choice, systematic mistakes, axiomatic foundation, utility estimation, dictator game |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C1 - Econometric and Statistical Methods and Methodology: General > C10 - General C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C9 - Design of Experiments > C90 - General D - Microeconomics > D0 - General > D03 - Behavioral Microeconomics: Underlying Principles |
Item ID: | 72779 |
Depositing User: | Yves Breitmoser |
Date Deposited: | 31 Jul 2016 04:45 |
Last Modified: | 30 Sep 2019 10:07 |
References: | Andersen, S., Harrison, G., Lau, M., and Rutström, E. (2008). Eliciting risk and time preferences. Econometrica, 76(3):583–618. Andreoni, J. and Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2):737–753. Bardsley, N. (2008). Dictator game giving: Altruism or artefact? Experimental Economics, 11(2):122–133. Battistin, E., Miniaci, R., and Weber, G. (2003). What do we learn from recall consumption data? Journal of Human Resources, 38(2):354–385. Bellemare, C., Kröger, S., and van Soest, A. (2008). Measuring inequity aversion in a heterogeneous population using experimental decisions and subjective probabilities. Econometrica, 76(4):815–839. Bernheim, B. D. and Rangel, A. (2009). Beyond revealed preference: choice-theoretic foundations for behavioral welfare economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(1):51–104. Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., and Pakes, A. (1995). Automobile prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica, 63(4):841–890. Bordalo, P., Gennaioli, N., and Shleifer, A. (2012). Salience theory of choice under risk. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(3):1243–1285. Breitmoser, Y. (2013). Estimation of social preferences in generalized dictator games. Economics Letters, 121(2):192–197. Breitmoser, Y. (2016). The axiomatic foundation of logit and its relation to behavioral welfare. MPRA Paper 71632. Camerer, C. (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Camerer, C., Ho, T., and Chong, J. (2004). A cognitive hierarchy model of games. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3):861–898. Camerer, C. and Ho, T. H. (1999). Experience-weighted attraction learning in normal form games. Econometrica, 67(4):827–874. Cappelen, A., Hole, A., Sørensen, E., and Tungodden, B. (2007). The pluralism of fairness ideals: An experimental approach. American Economic Review, 97(3):818–827. Covey, J. and Smith, R. (2006). How common is the prominence effect? additional evidence to whynes et al. Health economics, 15(2):205–210. Dana, J., Cain, D., and Dawes, R. (2006). What you don’t know won’t hurt me: Costly (but quiet) exit in dictator games. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 100(2):193–201. Dave, C., Eckel, C. C., Johnson, C. A., and Rojas, C. (2010). Eliciting risk preferences: When is simple better? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 41(3):219–243. Dean, M. L. (1980). Presentation order effects in product taste tests. The Journal of psychology, 105(1):107–110. Debreu, G. (1960). Review of 'Individual choice behavior’ by R. Luce. American Economic Review, 50:186–8. Dinner, I., Johnson, E. J., Goldstein, D. G., and Liu, K. (2011). Partitioning default effects: why people choose not to choose. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied, 17(4):332. Echenique, F., Saito, K., and Tserenjigmid, G. (2014). The perception-adjusted luce model. Working paper. Engel, C. (2011). Dictator games: a meta study. Experimental Economics, 14:583–610. Feenberg, D. R., Ganguli, I., Gaule, P., Gruber, J., et al. (2015). It’s good to be first: Order bias in reading and citing nber working papers. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research. Fisman, R., Kariv, S., and Markovits, D. (2007). Individual preferences for giving. American Economic Review, 97(5):1858–1876. Gul, F. and Pesendorfer, W. (2008). The case for mindless economics. The foundations of Positive and normative Economics: A handbook, pages 3–42. Harless, D. and Camerer, C. (1994). The predictive utility of generalized expected utility theories. Econometrica, pages 1251–1289. Harrison, G. W. and Johnson, L. T. (2006). Identifying altruism in the laboratory. In Isaac, R. M. and Davis, D. D., editors, Experiments Investigating Fundraising and Charitable Contributors, volume 11 of Research in experimental economics, pages 177–223. Emerald Group Publishing Limited. Harrison, G. W., List, J. A., and Towe, C. (2007). Naturally occurring preferences and exogenous laboratory experiments: A case study of risk aversion. Econometrica, 75(2):433–458. Heitjan, D. F. and Rubin, D. B. (1991). Ignorability and coarse data. Annals of Statistics, pages 2244–2253. Hey, J., Lotito, G., and Maffioletti, A. (2010). The descriptive and predictive adequacy of theories of decision making under uncertainty/ambiguity. Journal of risk and uncertainty, 41(2):81–111. Keane, M. P. (2010). Structural vs. atheoretic approaches to econometrics. Journal of Econometrics, 156(1):3–20. Keller, L. R. and Strazzera, E. (2002). Examining predictive accuracy among discounting models. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 24(2):143–160. Koszegi, B. and Rabin, M. (2008). Choices, situations, and happiness. Journal of Public Economics, 92(8):1821–1832. Koszegi, B. and Szeidl, A. (2013). A model of focusing in economic choice. The Quarterly journal of economics, 128(1):53–104. Lacetera, N., Pope, D. G., and Sydnor, J. R. (2012). Heuristic thinking and limited attention in the car market. American Economic Review, 102(5):2206–2236. Levine, D. K. (2012). Is behavioral economics doomed?: The ordinary versus the extraordinary. Open Book Publishers. List, J. (2007). On the interpretation of giving in dictator games. Journal of Political Economy, 115(3):482–493. Manski, C. F. and Molinari, F. (2010). Rounding probabilistic expectations in surveys. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 28(2):219–231. Manzini, P. and Mariotti, M. (2014). Stochastic choice and consideration sets. Econometrica, 82(3):1153–1176. Masatlioglu, Y., Nakajima, D., and Ozbay, E. Y. (2012). Revealed attention. American Economic Review, 102(5):2183–2205. Matejka, F. and McKay, A. (2015). Rational inattention to discrete choices: A new foundation for the multinomial logit model. American Economic Review, 105(1):272–98. McFadden, D. (1974). Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice models. Frontiers of Econometrics, ed. P. Zarembka. New York: Academic Press, pages 105–142. McFadden, D. (1976). Quantal choice analysis: A survey. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, 5(4):363–390. McKenzie, C. R., Liersch, M. J., and Finkelstein, S. R. (2006). Recommendations implicit in policy defaults. Psychological Science, 17(5):414–420. Miller, J. M. and Krosnick, J. A. (1998). The impact of candidate name order on election outcomes. Public Opinion Quarterly, 62:291–330. Nagelkerke, N. J. (1991). A note on a general definition of the coefficient of determination. Biometrika, 78(3):691–692. Padoa-Schioppa, C. (2009). Range-adapting representation of economic value in the orbitofrontal cortex. Journal of Neuroscience, 29(44):14004–14014. Padoa-Schioppa, C. and Rustichini, A. (2014). Rational attention and adaptive coding: a puzzle and a solution. The American economic review, 104(5):507. Poltrock, S. E. and Schwartz, D. R. (1984). Comparative judgments of multidigit numbers. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 10(1):32. Powell, M. (2006). The newuoa software for unconstrained optimization without derivatives. Large-Scale Nonlinear Optimization, pages 255–297. Read, D., Loewenstein, G., and Rabin, M. (1999). Choice bracketing. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19(1-3):171–97. Rust, J. (2010). Comments on: "structural vs. atheoretic approaches to econometrics" by Michael Keane. Journal of Econometrics, 156(1):21–24. Schennach, S. and Wilhelm, D. (2014). A simple parametric model selection test. Cemmap working paper. Schwarz, G. (1978). Estimating the dimension of a model. Annals of Statistics, 6(2):461–464. Small, K. (1987). A discrete choice model for ordered alternatives. Econometrica, 55(2):409–424. Train, K. (2003). Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge Univ Pr. Wasserstein, R. L. and Lazar, N. A. (2016). The asa’s statement on p-values: context, process, and purpose. The American Statistician (forthcoming). Whynes, D., Philips, Z., and Frew, E. (2005). Think of a number ... any number? Health Economics, 14(11):1191–1195. Wilcox, N. (2008). Stochastic models for binary discrete choice under risk: A critical primer and econometric comparison. In Cox, J. C. and Harrison, G. W., editors, Risk aversion in experiments, volume 12 of Research in experimental economics, pages 197–292. Emerald Group Publishing Limited. Wilcox, N. (2011). Stochastically more risk averse: A contextual theory of stochastic discrete choice under risk. Journal of Econometrics, 162(1):89–104. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/72779 |