Casey, Gregory (2017): Energy Efficiency and Directed Technical Change: Implications for Climate Change Mitigation.
This is the latest version of this item.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_80473.pdf Download (598kB) | Preview |
Abstract
In this paper, I construct a putty-clay model of directed technical change and use it to analyze the effect of environmental policy on energy use in the United States. The model matches key data patterns that cannot be explained by the standard Cobb-Douglas approach used in climate change economics. In particular, the model captures both the short- and long-run elasticity of substitution between energy and non-energy inputs, as well as trends in final-use energy efficiency. My primary analysis examines the impact of new energy taxes. The putty-clay model suggests that tax-inclusive energy prices need to be 273% higher than laissez-faire levels in 2055 in order to achieve policy goals consistent with international agreements. By contrast, the Cobb-Douglas approach suggests that prices need only be 136% higher. To meet the same goals, the putty-clay model implies that final good consumption must fall by 6.5% relative to a world without intervention, which is more than three times the prediction from the standard model. In a second analysis, I find that policy interventions cannot achieve long-run reductions in energy use without increasing prices, implying that energy efficiency mandates and R&D subsidies have limited potential as tools for climate change mitigation. Finally, I use the model to analyze the long-run sustainability of economic growth in a world with non-renewable resources. Using two definitions of sustainability, the new putty-clay model delivers results that are more optimistic than the existing literature.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Energy Efficiency and Directed Technical Change: Implications for Climate Change Mitigation |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Energy, Climate Change, Directed Technical Change, Growth |
Subjects: | H - Public Economics > H2 - Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue > H23 - Externalities ; Redistributive Effects ; Environmental Taxes and Subsidies O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O3 - Innovation ; Research and Development ; Technological Change ; Intellectual Property Rights > O30 - General O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O4 - Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity > O40 - General Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics ; Environmental and Ecological Economics > Q4 - Energy > Q40 - General Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics ; Environmental and Ecological Economics > Q5 - Environmental Economics > Q54 - Climate ; Natural Disasters and Their Management ; Global Warming |
Item ID: | 80473 |
Depositing User: | Gregory Casey |
Date Deposited: | 02 Aug 2017 09:16 |
Last Modified: | 27 Sep 2019 16:54 |
References: | Acemoglu, D. (1998): "Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1055-1089. Acemoglu, D. (2002): "Directed technical change," Review of Economic Studies, 69, 781-809. Acemoglu, D., P. Aghion, L. Bursztyn, and D. Hemous (2012): "The environment and directed technical change," American Economic Review, 102, 131-66. Acemoglu, D., U. Akcigit, D. Hanley, and W. Kerr (2016): "Transition to clean technology," Journal of Political Economy, 124, 52-104. Aghion, P., A. Dechezlepretre, D. Hemous, R. Martin, and J. Van Reenen (2016): "Carbon taxes, path dependency, and directed technical change: Evidence from the auto industry," Journal of Political Economy, 124, 1-51. Allcott, H. (2011): "Rethinking real-time electricity pricing," Resource and Energy Economics, 33, 820-842. Allcott, H. and M. Greenstone (2012): "Is there an energy efficiency gap?" Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26, 3-28. Anderson, S. T., R. Kellogg, and S. W. Salant (2014): "Hotelling under pressure," NBER Working Paper 20280. Andre, F. J. and S. Smulders (2014): "Fueling growth when oil peaks: Directed technological change and the limits to efficiency," European Economic Review, 69, 18-39. Anthoff, D. and R. S. Tol (2014): "The Climate Framework for Uncertainty, Negotiation and Distribution (FUND), technical description, version 3.8." Working Paper. Atkeson, A. and P. J. Kehoe (1999): "Models of energy use: Putty-putty versus putty-clay," American Economic Review, 89, 1028-1043. Barker, T., A. Dagoumas, and J. Rubin (2009): "The macroeconomic rebound effect and the world economy," Energy Efficiency, 2, 411. Barrage, L. (2014): "Optimal dynamic carbon taxes in a climate-economy model with distortionary fiscal policy," Working Paper. Baumeister, C. and L. Kilian (2016): "Forty years of oil price fluctuations: Why the price of oil may still surprise us," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30, 139-160. Borenstein, S. et al. (2015): "A microeconomic framework for evaluating energy efficiency rebound and some implications," Energy Journal, 36, 1-21. Bosetti, V., C. Carraro, M. Galeotti, E. Massetti, and M. Tavoni (2006): "A World induced Technical Change Hybrid Model," The Energy Journal. Calel, R. and A. Dechezlepretre (2016): "Environmental policy and directed technological change: Evidence from the European carbon market," Review of Economics and Statistics, 98, 173-191. Calvo, G. A. (1976): "Optimal growth in a putty-clay model," Econometrica, 867-878. Cass, D. and J. E. Stiglitz (1969): "The implications of alternative saving and expectations hypotheses for choices of technique and patterns of growth," Journal of Political Economy, 586-627. Covert, T., M. Greenstone, and C. R. Knittel (2016): "Will we ever stop using fossil fuels?" Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30, 117-137. Crassous, R., J.-C. Hourcade, and O. Sassi (2006): "Endogenous structural change and climate targets modeling experiments with Imaclim-R," Energy Journal, 259-276. Dechezlepretre, A., M. Glachant, I. Hascic, N. Johnstone, and Y. Meniere (2011): "Invention and transfer of climate change-mitigation technologies: A global analysis," Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 5, 109-130. Di Maria, C. and S. Valente (2008): "Hicks meets Hotelling: The direction of technical change in capital-resource economies," Environment and Development Economics, 13, 691-717. Di Maria, C. and E. Van der Werf (2008): "Carbon leakage revisited: Unilateral climate policy with directed technical change," Environmental and Resource Economics, 39, 55-74. Fowlie, M., M. Greenstone, and C. Wolfram (2015): "Do energy efficiency investments deliver? Evidence from the weatherization assistance program," NBER Working Paper No. 21331. Fried, S. (forthcoming): "Climate policy and innovation: A quantitative macroeconomic analysis," American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. Gans, J. S. (2012): "Innovation and climate change policy," American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 125-145. Gillingham, K. (2014): "Rebound effects," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Gillingham, K., R. G. Newell, and K. Palmer (2009):"Energy efficiency economics and policy," Annual Review of Resource Economics, 1, 597-620. Gillingham, K., D. Rapson, and G. Wagner (2015): "The rebound effect and energy efficiency policy," Working Paper. Gillingham, K., D. Rapson, and G. Wagner (2016): "The Rebound Effect and Energy Efficiency Policy," Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 10, 68-88. Golosov, M., J. Hassler, P. Krusell, and A. Tsyvinski (2014): "Optimal taxes on fossil fuel in general equilibrium," Econometrica, 82, 41-88. Goulder, L. H. and K. Mathai (2000): "Optimal CO2 abatement in the presence of induced technological change," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 39, 1-38. Goulder, L. H. and S. H. Schneider (1999): "Induced technological change and the attractiveness of CO2 abatement policies," Resource and Energy Economics, 21, 211-253. Grimaud, A. and L. Rouge (2008): "Environment, directed technical change and economic policy," Environmental and Resource Economics, 41, 439-463. Hamilton, J. D. (2012): "Oil prices, exhaustible resources, and economic growth," NBER Working Paper 17759. Hart, R. (2004): "Growth, environment and innovation -- a model with production vintages and environmentally oriented research," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 48, 1078-1098. Hart, R. (2008): "The timing of taxes on CO 2 emissions when technological change is endogenous," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 55, 194-212. Hart, R. (2013): "Directed technological change and factor shares," Economics Letters, 119, 77-80. Hart, R. and D. Spiro (2011): "The elephant in Hotelling's room," Energy Policy, 39, 7834-7838. Hassler, J., P. Krusell, and J. Nycander (2016a): "Climate policy," Economic Policy, 31, 503-558. Hassler, J., P. Krusell, and C. Olovsson (2012): "Energy-saving technical change," NBER Working Paper No. 18456. Hassler, J., P. Krusell, and C. Olovsson (2016b): "Directed technical change as a response to natural-resource scarcity," Working Paper. Heal, G. (1976): "The relationship between price and extraction cost for a resource with a backstop technology," Bell Journal of Economics, 371-378. Hemous, D. (2016): "The dynamic impact of unilateral environmental policies," Journal of International Economics, 103, 80-95. Hope, C. (2011): "The PAGE09 integrated assessment model: A technical description," Working Paper. Hotelling, H. (1931): "The economics of exhaustible resources," Journal of Political Economy, 137-175. Jaffe, A. B., R. G. Newell, and R. N. Stavins (2003): "Technological change and the environment," Handbook of Environmental Economics, 1, 461-516. Jessoe, K. and D. Rapson (2014): "Knowledge is (less) power: Experimental evidence from residential energy use," American Economic Review, 104, 1417-1438. Johansen, L. (1959): Substitution versus fixed production coefficients in the theory of economic growth: A synthesis," Econometrica, 157-176. Lemoine, D. (2016): "General equilibrium rebound from energy efficiency policies," Working Paper. Lemoine, D. (2017): "Innovation-led transitions in energy supply," Working Paper. Lin, C.-Y. C. and G. Wagner (2007): "Steady-state growth in a Hotelling model of resource extraction," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 54, 68-83. Metcalf, G. E. (2008): "An empirical analysis of energy intensity and its determinants at the state level," Energy Journal, 1-26. Morris, J., S. Paltsev, and J. Reilly (2012): "Marginal abatement costs and marginal welfare costs for greenhouse gas emissions reductions: Results from the EPPA model," Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 17, 325-336. Newell, R. G., A. B. Jaffe, and R. N. Stavins (1999): "The induced innovation hypothesis and energy-saving technological change," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 941-975. Nordhaus, W. (2014): "Estimates of the social cost of carbon: Concepts and results from the DICE-2013R model and alternative approaches," Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 1, 273-312. Nordhaus, W. D. (1993): "Optimal greenhouse-gas reductions and tax policy in the "DICE" model," American Economic Review, 83, 313-317. Nordhaus, W. D. (2010): "Economic aspects of global warming in a post-Copenhagen environment," Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 107, 11721-11726. Nordhaus, W. D. (2013): The climate casino: Risk, uncertainty, and economics for a warming world, Yale University Press. Nordhaus, W. D. and J. Boyer (2000): Warming the world: Economic models of global warming, MIT press. Peretto, P. F. (2008): "Effluent taxes, market structure, and the rate and direction of endogenous technological change," Environmental and Resource Economics, 39, 113-138. Peretto, P. F. and S. Valente (2015): "Growth on a finite planet: Resources, technology and population in the long run," Journal of Economic Growth, 20, 305-331. Pindyck, R. S. (1978): "The optimal exploration and production of nonrenewable resources," Journal of Political Economy, 841-861. Pindyck, R. S. (1999): "The long-run evolution of energy prices," Energy Journal, 1-27. Pindyck, R. S. and J. J. Rotemberg (1983): "Dynamic factor demands and the effects of energy price shocks," American Economic Review, 73, 1066-1079. Popp, D. (2002): "Induced innovation and energy prices," American Economic Review, 92, 160-180. Popp, D. (2004): "ENTICE: Endogenous technological change in the DICE model of global warming," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 48, 742-768. Popp, D., R. G. Newell, and A. B. Jaffe (2010): "Energy, the environment, and technological change," Handbook of the Economics of Innovation, 2, 873-937. Ricci, F. (2007): "Environmental policy and growth when inputs are differentiated in pollution intensity," Environmental and Resource Economics, 38, 285-310. Rogner, H.-H. (1997): "An assessment of world hydrocarbon resources," Annual Review of Energy and the Environment, 22, 217-262. Rogner, H.-H., L. A. LA, R. F. Aguilera, C. L. Archer, R. Bertani, S. Bhattacharya, M. B. Dusseault, L. Gagnon, H. Haberl, et al. (2012): "Energy Resources and Potentials," in Global energy assessment: Toward a sustainable future, ed. by T. B. Johansson, A. P. Patwardhan, N. Nakicenovic, and L. Gomez-Echeverri, Cambridge University Press. Slade, M. E. (1982): "Trends in natural-resource commodity prices: An analysis of the time domain," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 9, 122-137. Smulders, S. and M. De Nooij (2003): "The impact of energy conservation on technology and economic growth," Resource and Energy Economics, 25, 59-79. Solow, R. M. (1962): "Substitution and fixed proportions in the theory of capital," Review of Economic Studies, 29, 207-218. Solow, R. M. and F. Y. Wan (1976): "Extraction costs in the theory of exhaustible resources," Bell Journal of Economics, 359-370. Sorrell, S. et al. (2007): "The Rebound Effect: an assessment of the evidence for economy-wide energy savings from improved energy efficiency," Report for the UK Energy Research Center. Sue Wing, I. (2003): "Induced technical change and the cost of climate policy," MIT Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change Report No. 102. Sue Wing, I. (2008): "Explaining the declining energy intensity of the US economy," Resource and Energy Economics, 30, 21-49. Turner, K. (2009): "Negative rebound and disinvestment effects in response to an improvement in energy efficiency in the UK economy," Energy Economics, 31, 648 666. van der Ploeg, F. and C. Withagen (2012): "Too much coal, too little oil," Journal of Public Economics, 96, 62-77. Van der Werf, E. (2008): "Production functions for climate policy modeling: An empirical analysis," Energy Economics, 30, 2964-2979. Wei, T. (2010): "A general equilibrium view of global rebound effects," Energy Economics, 32, 661-672. Weyant, J. (2017): "Some contributions of integrated assessment models of global climate change," Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 11, 115-137. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/80473 |
Available Versions of this Item
-
Energy Efficiency and Directed Technical Change: Implications for Climate Change Mitigation. (deposited 26 Jan 2017 13:14)
- Energy Efficiency and Directed Technical Change: Implications for Climate Change Mitigation. (deposited 02 Aug 2017 09:16) [Currently Displayed]