Accolley, Delali (2016): Accounting for Business Cycles in Canada: I. The Role of Supply-Side Factors.
This is the latest version of this item.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_81778.pdf Download (600kB) | Preview |
Abstract
After documenting business cycle facts in Canada, I have explained them using some popular models, which include: the indivisible labor, the time-to-build, the investment-specific technological change, the household production, and the human capital accumulation models. The common features of these models called real business cycle models are: the use of the neoclassical growth framework, the assumption that prices are flexible, and the reliance on supply-side factors, mainly technological change, to explain business cycles.
I have assessed the ability of these models to replicate some striking features of business cycles, which are: the high persistence in the fluctuations of the aggregate economic variables, the high correlation between total hours worked and output, and the absence of correlation between average hours worked and productivity. The model that passes these three tests is the household production model augmented with a human capital accumulation sector. All alone, the household production model replicates the persistence in the dynamics of the aggregate variables but has to rely on the endogenous growth mechanism to generate the near-zero correlation between average hours worked and productivity.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Accounting for Business Cycles in Canada: I. The Role of Supply-Side Factors |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Macroeconomics, Business Cycle |
Subjects: | E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E3 - Prices, Business Fluctuations, and Cycles > E32 - Business Fluctuations ; Cycles |
Item ID: | 81778 |
Depositing User: | Delali Accolley |
Date Deposited: | 11 Oct 2017 13:21 |
Last Modified: | 30 Sep 2019 19:51 |
References: | Accolley, D. (2016): “Accounting for Business Cycles in Canada: II. The Role of Money Supply” . Baxter, M., and G. King, Robert (1999): “Measuring Business Cycle: Approximate Band-Pass Filters for Economic Time Series,” Journal of Economics and Statistics, 81, 575–93. Benhabib, J., R. Rogerson, and R. Wright (1991): “Homework in Macroeconomics: Household Production and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Journal of Political Economy, 99(61), 1166–87. Canova, F. (1998a): “Detrending and Business Cycle Facts,” Journal ofMonetary Economics, 41, 475–512. Canova, F. (1998b): “Detrending and Business Cycle Facts: A User’s Guide,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 41, 533–40. Chari, V. V., P. J. Kehoe, and E. R. McGrattan (2007): “Business cycle accounting, Econometrica,75(3), 781–836. Cociuba, S. E., and A. Ueberfeldt (2008): Driving forces of the Canadian economy: an accounting exercise. Bank of Canada Ottawa, ON. Cooley, Thomas, F., and G. D. Hansen (1989): “The Role of Inflation Tax in a Real Business Cycle Model,” The American Economic Review, 79(9), 733–48. Cooley, Thomas, F., and G. D. Hansen (1995): Money and the Business Cycle, Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, pp. 174–216. Cooley, Thomas, F., and G. D. Hansen (1998): “The Role of Monetary Shock in Equilibrium Business Cycle Theory: Three Examples,” European Economic Review, 42, 605–17. Cooley, T. F., and E. C. Prescott (1995): Economic Growth and Business Cycle, Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, pp. 1–38. Cross, P., and P. Bergevin (2012):“Turning points: business cycles in Canada since 1926,”CD Howe Institute, 366. DeJong, David, N., and B. Ingram (2001): “The Cyclical Behavior of Skill Acquisition,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 4, 536–61. Einarsson, T., and M. H. Marquis (1997): “Home Production and Endogenous Growth,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 39, 551–569. Gali, J. (1999): “Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations?,” The American Economic Review, 89(1), 249–71. Gangopadhyay, K., and J. C. Hatchondo (2009): “The Behavior of Household and Business Investment over the Business Cycle,” Economic Quarterly, 95(3), 269–88. Gavin, William, T., and F. E. Kydland (1999): “Endogenous Money Supply and Business Cycle,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 2, 347–369. Gomme, P., F. E. Kydland, and P. Rupert (2001): “Home production meets time to build,” Journal of Political Economy, 109(5), 1115–1131. Gomme, P., and Rupert (2006): “Theory, Measurement, and Calibration of Macroeconomic Models,” . Greenwood, J., and z. Hercowitz (1991): “The Allocation of Capital and Time over the Business Cycle,” Journal of Political Economy, 99, 1188–1214. Greenwood, J., Z. Hercowitz, and P. Krusell (1997): “Long-Run Implications of Investment-Specific Technological Change,” The American Economic Review, 87(3), 342–62. Greenwood, J., Z. Hercowitz, and P. Krusell (2000): “The Role of Investment-Specific Technological Change in Business Cycle,” The European Economic Review, 44, 91–115. Greenwood, J., R. Rogerson, and R. Wright (1995): Household Production in Real Business Cycle Theory, Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, pp. 157–74. Griffoli, T. M. (2007): “Dynare user guide: An introduction to the solution and estimation of DSGE models,” Manuscript, http://www.cepremap. cnrs. fr/dynare. Hamilton, James, D. (1994): Time Series Analysis. Princeton University Press. Hansen, G. D. (1985): “Indivisible Labor and the Business Cycle,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 16, 309–27. Hansen, G. D., and R. Wright (1992): “The Labor Market in Real Business Cycle Theory,” (1621). Hodrick, Robert, J., and E C. Prescott (1997): “Postwar US Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigations,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29 (1), 1–16. King, Robert, G., C E. Plosser, and S. J. Rebelo (1988): “Production, Growth, and Business Cycle: I. The Basic Neoclassical Model,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 21, 195–232. King, Robert, G., C E. Plosser, and S. J. Rebelo (1988): “Production, Growth, and Business Cycle: II. The New Definitions,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 21, 195–232. King, Robert, G., and S. T. Rebelo (2000): “Resuscitating Real Business Cycles,” (7534). Kydland, Finn, E., and E. C. Prescott (1982): “Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Econometrica, 80,1345–70. Ljungovist, L., and T. J. Sargent (2004): Recursive Macroeconomic Theory. Lucas Jr, Robert, E. (1975): “An Equilibrium Model of the Business Cycle,” Journal of Political Economy, 83, 1113–44. Lucas Jr, Robert, E. (1980): “Methods and Problems in Business Cycle Theory,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 12, 6963–715. Mas-Colell, A., M. D. Winston, and J. R. Green (1995): Microeconomic Theory. Sargent, T. J. (1987): Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory. Stockey, N. L., R. E. Lucas Jr, and E. C. Prescott (1989): Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. Varian, H. R. (1992): Microeconomic Analysis. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/81778 |
Available Versions of this Item
-
Accounting for Business Cycles in Canada: I. The Role of Supply-Side Factors. (deposited 08 Mar 2016 14:34)
-
Accounting for Business Cycles in Canada: I. The Role of Supply-Side Factors. (deposited 20 Mar 2016 20:54)
- Accounting for Business Cycles in Canada: I. The Role of Supply-Side Factors. (deposited 11 Oct 2017 13:21) [Currently Displayed]
-
Accounting for Business Cycles in Canada: I. The Role of Supply-Side Factors. (deposited 20 Mar 2016 20:54)