Kuehnhanss, Colin R and Heyndels, Bruno and Hilken, Katharina (2015): Choice in politics: Equivalency framing in economic policy decisions and the influence of expertise. Published in: European Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 40, No. pt.B (9 December 2015): pp. 360-374.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_85309.pdf Download (438kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Political decision-making involves the presentation of policy options from opposing points of view and in different lights. We test whether economic policy decisions are subject to equivalency framing by presenting survey participants with binary risky-choice decisions in hypothetical policy scenarios. Potentially mediating influences of expertise on the framing effect are explored using responses of students and professionals. Expertise is thereby defined in line with common education and work experience criteria in the recruitment of public officials. We mostly find unidirectional framing effects in the economic policy scenarios and a similar susceptibility of respondents with different levels of expertise. A logistic regression of the expertise variables on the choice between certain and risky options reveals only the frame to have a systematically significant effect across scenarios. The results indicate that expertise may not necessarily help to make better policy choices under risk, if the available options are framed differently.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Choice in politics: Equivalency framing in economic policy decisions and the influence of expertise |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Equivalency framing; Political decision-making; Economic policy; Expertise |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D73 - Bureaucracy ; Administrative Processes in Public Organizations ; Corruption D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty > D81 - Criteria for Decision-Making under Risk and Uncertainty |
Item ID: | 85309 |
Depositing User: | Colin Kuehnhanss |
Date Deposited: | 24 Apr 2018 17:18 |
Last Modified: | 27 Sep 2019 13:25 |
References: | Afonso, A., 2007. Policy change and the politics of expertise: Economic ideas and immigration control reforms in Switzerland. Swiss Political Science Review 13(1), 1-38. DOI: 10.1002/j.1662-6370.2007.tb00068.x. Bazerman, M.H., 1984. The relevance of Kahneman and Tversky’s concept of framing to organizational behavior. Journal of Management 10(3), 333-343. DOI: 10.1177/014920638401000307. Bendor, J., 2010. Bounded Rationality and Politics. Volume 6. Berkley: University of California Press. Bless, H., Betsch, T., Franzen, A., 1998. Framing the framing effect: The impact of context cues on solutions to the 'Asian disease' problem. European Journal of Social Psychology 28(2), 287-291. DOI: 10.1002/(SICI)1099-0992(199803/04)28:2<287::AID-EJSP861>3.0.CO;2-U. Boettcher, W.A., 2004. The prospects for prospect theory: An empirical evaluation of international relations applications of framing and loss aversion. Political Psychology 25(3), 331-362. DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-9221.2004.00375.x. Bohm, P., Lind, H., 1992. A note on the robustness of a classical framing result. Journal of Economic Psychology 13(2), 355-361. DOI: 10.1016/0167-4870(92)90039-A. Boswell, C., 2008. The political functions of expert knowledge: Knowledge and legitimation in European Union immigration policy. Journal of European Public Policy 15(4), 471-488. DOI: 10.1080/13501760801996634. Bütler, M., Maréchal, M., 2007. Framing effects in political decision making: Evidence from a natural voting experiment. CESifo Working Paper No. 1940. URL: http://www.econstor.eu/dspace/bitstream/10419/25985/1/538080965.PDF. Byrnes, J.P., Miller, D.C., Schafer, W.D., 1999. Gender differences in risk taking: A meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin 125(3), 367-383. DOI: 10.1037//0033-2909.125.3.367. Caplan, B., 2001. What makes people think like economists? Evidence on economic cognition from the "Survey of Americans and Economists on the Economy". Journal of Law and Economics 44(2), 395-426. DOI: 10.1086/322812. Christensen, J., 2015. Recruitment and expertise in the European Commission. West European Politics 38(3), 649-678. DOI: 10.1080/01402382.2014.982353. Cooper, J.C., Kovacic, W.E., 2012. Behavioral economics: Implications for regulatory behavior. Journal of Regulatory Economics 41(1), 41-58. DOI: 10.1007/s11149-011-9180-1. Druckman, J., 2001. Evaluating framing effects. Journal of Economic Psychology 22(1), 91-101. DOI: 10.1016/S0167-4870(00)00032-5. Druckman, J., McDermott, R., 2008. Emotion and the framing of risky choice. Political Behavior 30(3), 297-321. DOI: 10.1007/s11109-008-9056-y. Eckel, C.C., Grossman, P.J., 2008. Men, women and risk aversion: Experimental evidence. Handbook of Experimental Economics Results 1, 1061-1073. DOI: 10.1016/s1574-0722(07)00113-8. Emler, N., Frazer, E., 1999. Politics: The education effect. Oxford Review of Education 25(1-2), 251-273. DOI: 10.1080/030549899104242. European Commission, 2012a. Gender equality in the European Commission. URL: http://ec.europa.eu/justice/gender-equality/files/womenonboards/factsheet-general-4_en.pdf. European Commission, 2012b. Permanent officials. URL: http://ec.europa.eu/civil_service/job/official/index_en.htm. European Parliament, 2014. Women in the European Parliament. URL: http://www.europarl.europa.eu/RegData/publications/2014/0001/P7_PUB(2014)0001_EN.pdf. Fagley, N.S., Miller, P.M., 1987. The effects of decision framing on choice of risky vs certain options. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 39(2), 264-277. DOI: 10.1016/0749-5978(87)90041-0. Fagley, N.S., Miller, P.M., 1990. The effect of framing on choice interactions with risk-taking propensity, cognitive style, and sex. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 16(3), 496-510. DOI: 10.1177/0146167290163008. Fellner, G., Maciejovsky, B., 2007. Risk attitude and market behavior: Evidence from experimental asset markets. Journal of Economic Psychology 28(3), 338-350. DOI: 10.1016/j.joep.2007.01.006. Fiske, S.T., Kinder, D.R., Larter, W.M., 1983. The novice and the expert: Knowledge-based strategies in political cognition. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 19(4), 381-400. DOI: 10.1016/0022-1031(83)90029-X. Frisch, D., 1993. Reasons for framing effects. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 54(3), 399-429. DOI: 10.1006/obhd.1993.1017. Green, D.P., Shapiro, I., 1994. Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory: A Critique of Applications in Political Science. New Haven: Yale University Press. Harstad, R.M., Selten, R., 2016. Diminished-dimensional political economy. European Economic Review 83, 213-219. DOI: 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.08.006 Henrich, J., Heine, S.J., Norenzayan, A., 2010. The weirdest people in the world? Behavioral and Brain Sciences 33(2-3), 61-135. DOI: 10.1017/S0140525X0999152X. Igou, E.R., Bless, H., 2007. On undesirable consequences of thinking: Framing effects as a function of substantive processing. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 20(2), 125-142. DOI: 10.1002/bdm.543. Kahan, D.M., Dawson, E.C., Peters, E., Slovic, P., 2013. Motivated numeracy and enlightened self-government. Yale Law School, The Cultural Cognition Project, Working Paper (116). URL: http://www.cogsci.bme.hu/~ktkuser/KURZUSOK/BMETE47MC15/2013_2014_1/kahanEtAl2013.pdf. Kahneman, D., 1992. Reference points, anchors, norms, and mixed feelings. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 51(2), 296-312. DOI: 10.1016/0749-5978(92)90015-Y. Kahneman, D., 2003. Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. American Economic Review 93(5), 1449-1475. DOI: 10.1257/000282803322655392. Kahneman, D., Tversky, A., 1979. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2), 263-291. DOI: 10.2307/1914185. Kahneman, D., Tversky, A., 2000. Choices, Values, and Frames. Cambridge University Press, New York. Kam, C.D., Simas, E.N., 2010. Risk orientations and policy frames. The Journal of Politics 72(2), 381-396. DOI: 10.1017/S0022381609990806. Kassim, H., Peterson, J., Bauer, M.W., Connolly, S., Dehousse, R., Hooghe, L., Thompson, A., 2013. The European Commission of the Twenty-First Century. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Kirchgässner, G., 2005. (Why) are economists different? European Journal of Political Economy 21(3), 543-562. DOI: 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2005.05.003. Köszegi, B., Rabin, M., 2006. A model of reference-dependent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(4), 1133-1165. DOI: 10.1093/qje/121.4.1133. Köszegi, B., Rabin, M., 2007. Reference-dependent risk attitudes. American Economic Review 97(4), 1047-1073. DOI: 10.1257/aer.97.4.1047. Krosnick, J., 1990. Expertise and political psychology. Social Cognition 8(1), 1-8. DOI: 10.1521/soco.1990.8.1.1. Kühberger, A., 1998. The influence of framing on risky decisions: A meta-analysis. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 75(1), 23-55. DOI: 10.1006/obhd.1998.2781. Kühberger, A., Schulte-Mecklenbeck, M., Perner, J., 1999. The effects of framing, reflection, probability, and payoff on risk preference in choice tasks. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 78(3), 204-231. DOI: 10.1006/obhd.1999.2830. Kühberger, A., Tanner, C., 2010. Risky choice framing: Task versions and a comparison of prospect theory and fuzzy-trace theory. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 23(3), 314-329. DOI: 10.1002/bdm.656. Lawrence, E.D., 2010. What Americans know and why it matters for politics, Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association. URL: http://projects.iq.harvard.edu/files/cces/files/Lawrence-_What_Americans_Know.pdf. LeBoeuf, R.A., Shafir, E., 2003. Deep thoughts and shallow frames: On the susceptibility to framing effects. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 16(2), 77-92. DOI: 10.1002/bdm.433. Levin, I., Gaeth, G., Schreiber, J., 2002. A new look at framing effects: Distribution of effect sizes, individual differences, and independence of types of effects. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 88(1), 411-429. DOI: 10.1006/obhd.2001.2983. Levin, I., Snyder, M., Chapman, D., 1988. The interaction of experiential and situational factors and gender in a simulated risky decision-making task. The Journal of Psychology 122(2), 173-181. DOI: 10.1080/00223980.1988.9712703. Levy, J., 1997. Prospect theory, rational choice, and international relations. International Studies Quarterly 41(1), 87-112. DOI: 10.1111/0020-8833.00034. Levy, J., 2003. Applications of prospect theory to political science. Synthese 135(2), 215-241. DOI: 10.1023/A:1023413007698. Linde, J., Vis, B., 2014. Do behavioral theories like prospect theory apply to political actors? An experimental test on a sample of Dutch parliamentarians and students, Dutch/Flemish Politicologenetmaal, Maastricht, The Netherlands. List, J.A., 2004. Neoclassical theory versus prospect theory: Evidence from the marketplace. Econometrica 72(2), 615-625. DOI: 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2004.00502.x. Loewen, P.J., Sheffer, L., Soroka, S., Walgrave, S., Shaefer, T., 2014. Expertise and efficacy in elite political decision making, Behavioral Models of Politics Conference, Duke University. URL: http://sites.duke.edu/2014bmp/files/2014/10/Loewen_et_al.pdf. Mayhorn, C.B., Fisk, A.D., Whittle, J.D., 2002. Decisions, decisions: Analysis of age, cohort, and time of testing on framing of risky decision options. Human Factors: The Journal of the Human Factors and Ergonomics Society 44(4), 515-521. DOI: 10.1518/0018720024496935. McDermott, R., 1998. Risk-Taking in International Politics: Prospect theory in American Foreign Policy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. McDermott, R., 2004. Prospect theory in political science: Gains and losses from the first decade. Political Psychology 25(2), 289-312. DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-9221.2004.00372.x. Mercer, J., 2005. Prospect theory and political science. Annual Review of Political Science 8, 1-21. DOI: 10.1146/annurev.polisci.8.082103.104911. Meza, D., Webb, D.C., 2007. Incentive design under loss aversion. Journal of the European Economic Association 5(1), 66-92. DOI: 10.1162/JEEA.2007.5.1.66. von Neumann, J., Morgenstern, O., 1947. The Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton University Press. Nordstokke, D.W., Zumbo, B.D., Cairns, S.L., Saklofske, D.H., 2011. The operating characteristics of the nonparametric Levene test for equal variances with assessment and evaluation data. Practical Assessment, Research & Evaluation 16(5), 1-8. Nullmeier, F., 2005. Knowledge and decision-making, in: Maasen, S., Weingart, P. (Eds.), Democratization of Expertise? Exploring Novel Forms of Scientific Advice in Political Decision-Making. Springer Netherlands, pp. 123-134. DOI: 10.1007/1-4020-3754-6_7. Peters, B.G., 2005. Institutional Theory in Political Science: The new Institutionalism. 2 ed, London: Continuum. Peters, E., Levin, I.P., 2008. Dissecting the risky-choice framing effect: Numeracy as an individual-difference factor in weighting risky and riskless options. Judgment and Decision Making 3(6), 435-448. Peters, E., Västfjäll, D., Slovic, P., Mertz, C., Mazzocco, K., Dickert, S., 2006. Numeracy and decision making. Psychological Science 17(5), 407-413. DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-9280.2006.01720.x. Pollack, M.A., 2006. Rational choice and EU politics, in: Jørgensen, K.E., Pollack, M.A., Rosamond, B. (Eds.), Handbook of European Union Politics. London: Sage, pp. 31-55. DOI: 10.4135/9781848607903. Powell, M., Ansic, D., 1997. Gender differences in risk behaviour in financial decision-making: An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology 18(6), 605-628. DOI: 10.1016/S0167-4870(97)00026-3. Quattrone, G.A., Tversky, A., 1988. Contrasting rational and psychological analyses of political choice. American Political Science Review 82(3), 719-736. DOI: 10.2307/1962487. Radaelli, C., 1999. The public policy of the European Union: Whither politics of expertise? Journal of European Public Policy 6(5), 757-774. DOI: 10.1080/135017699343360. Rayner, S., 2003. Democracy in the age of assessment: Reflections on the roles of expertise and democracy in public-sector decision making. Science and Public Policy 30(3), 163-170. DOI: 10.3152/147154303781780533. Rönnlund, M., Karlsson, E., Laggnäs, E., Larsson, L., Lindström, T., 2005. Risky decision making across three arenas of choice: Are younger and older adults differently susceptible to framing effects? The Journal of General Psychology 132(1), 81-93. DOI: 10.3200/GENP.132.1.81-93. Schmidt, U., Starmer, C., Sugden, R., 2008. Third-generation prospect theory. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 36(3), 203-223. DOI: 10.1007/s11166-008-9040-2. Schnellenbach, J., Schubert, C., 2014. Behavioral political economy: A survey. CESifo Working Paper (No. 4988). URL: http://www.cesifo-group.de/portal/page/portal/lang-en/DocBase_Content/WP/WP-CESifo_Working_Papers/wp-cesifo-2014/wp-cesifo-2014-09/cesifo1_wp4988.pdf. Shiloh, S., Salton, E., Sharabi, D., 2002. Individual differences in rational and intuitive thinking styles as predictors of heuristic responses and framing effects. Personality and Individual Differences 32(3), 415-429. DOI: 10.1016/S0191-8869(01)00034-4. Simon, A.F., Fagley, N., Halleran, J.G., 2004. Decision draming: Moderating effects of individual differences and cognitive processing. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 17(2), 77-93. DOI: 10.1002/bdm.463. Simon, H.A., 1995. Rationality in political behavior. Political Psychology 16(1), 45-61. DOI: 10.2307/3791449. Strøm, K., 2000. Delegation and accountability in parliamentary democracies. European Journal of Political Research 37(3), 261-290. DOI: 10.1023/A:1007064803327. Tversky, A., Kahneman, D., 1981. The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science 211(4481), 453-458. DOI: 10.1126/science.7455683. Tversky, A., Kahneman, D., 1986. Rational choice and the framing of decisions. The Journal of Business 59(4/2), S251-S278. DOI: 10.1086/296365. Tversky, A., Kahneman, D., 1992. Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5(4), 297-323. DOI: 10.1007/BF00122574. Wang, X., 1996. Framing effects: Dynamics and task domains. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 68(2), 145-157. DOI: 10.1006/obhd.1996.0095. Wiseman, D.B., Levin, I.P., 1996. Comparing risky decision making under conditions of real and hypothetical consequences. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 66(3), 241-250. DOI: 10.1006/obhd.1996.0053. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/85309 |