Mendez-Guerra, Carlos (2019): Investment Constraints and Productivity Cycles in Bolivia.
PDF
MPRA_paper_91861.pdf Download (366kB) |
Abstract
Bolivia has suffered from a series of investment constraints and negative productivity cycles in the last half-century. In this context, this article first presents suggestive empirical evidence that physical capital accumulation has been constrained by high volatility in investment per worker, low marginal product of capital, and high adjustment costs. Next, the article presents evidence about the cyclical behavior of Bolivia’s total factor productivity (TFP) during the 1980-2008 period. As expected, the cyclical dynamics of TFP are shaped by cyclical variables such as terms of trade and fluctuations in the real exchange. However, economic policy variables (such as macroeconomic stabilization and external debt management), institutional variables (such as democracy and civil rights) and initial conditions also appear to be significant when explaining the behavior of Bolivia’s TFP.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Investment Constraints and Productivity Cycles in Bolivia |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | investment, productivity, capital accumulation, Bolivia |
Subjects: | O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O4 - Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity > O40 - General O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O4 - Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity > O47 - Empirical Studies of Economic Growth ; Aggregate Productivity ; Cross-Country Output Convergence O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O5 - Economywide Country Studies O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O5 - Economywide Country Studies > O54 - Latin America ; Caribbean |
Item ID: | 91861 |
Depositing User: | Carlos Mendez-Guerra |
Date Deposited: | 31 Jan 2019 14:56 |
Last Modified: | 26 Sep 2019 13:12 |
References: | Caselli, F. (2007). The marginal product of capital. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2):535–568. Chenery, H. (1952). Overcapacity and the acceleration principle. Econometrica, 20(1):128. Cochrane, D.and Orcutt, G. (1949). Application of least squares regression to relationships containing auto-correlated error terms. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 44:32–61. Fuentes, R., Larra´ın, M., and Schmidt-Hebbel, K. (2006). Sources of growth and behavior of tfp in chile. Cuadernos de Economia-Latin American Journal of Economics, 43(127):113–142. Harberger, A. C. (1998). A vision of the growth process. American Economic Review, 88(1):1–32. Harrod, R. (1936). The Trade Cycle. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Hendry, D., editor (1995). Dynamic Econometrics. Princeton University Press, New Yersey. Kopcke, R. W. and Brauman, R. S. (2001). The performance of traditional macroeconomic models of businesses’ investment spending. New England Economic Review,pages 3–39. Koyck, L. (1954). Distributed Lags and Investment Analysis. North-Holland, Amsterdam. Laserna, R. (2004). Democracy under Entanglement ( Translated from ”La Democracia en el Chenko”, Spanish version). Fundacion Millenio. Lucas, R. (1990). Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? American Economic Review, 80(2):92–96. Marquetti, A. (2011). Extended Penn world tables v. 4.0. Mendieta, P. and Martin, D. (2008). En busca de los determinantes del crecimiento economico boliviano. Documentos de Trabajo Banco Central de Bolivia. Morales, J. A. and Sachs, J. (1988). Bolivia’s economic crisis. NBER Working Papers 2620, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Newey, W. K. and West, K. D. (1987). A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55(3):703–08. Pigou, A. (1929). Industrial Fluctuations. Macmillan, London. Prais, S. and Winsten, C. (1954). Trend estimators and serial correlation. Working Paper 383, Cowles Commission. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/91861 |