Farina, Francesco and Sbriglia, Patrizia (2007): Cooperation as self-interested reciprocity in the Centipede.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_3701.pdf Download (263kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Cooperation is a pervasive social phenomenon but more often than not economic theories have little to say about its causes and consequences. In this paper, we explore the hypothesis that cooperative behaviour might be motivated by purely selfish interest when the “social” payoff in a game is increasing. We report the results of a series of experiments on the centipede game. The experiments are organized in two subsequent steps. Subjects first participate in a 2-period trust game, randomly matched with unknown partners. We apply the strategy method in order to elicit their social preferences. On the basis of their pre-game behaviour, individuals are divided into three main social groups: selfish individuals, pure altruists and reciprocators. At the second step of the experiment, subjects play a repeated 6-move centipede game with increasing final payoff. Each subject plays twice in a low stake and in a high centipede game, and he/she is informed about his/her co-player social preferences. We identify the origin of cooperation within homogeneous and heterogeneous social groups.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Institution: | university of siena -university of Naples II |
Original Title: | Cooperation as self-interested reciprocity in the Centipede |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | social preferences; altruisms; experiments |
Subjects: | A - General Economics and Teaching > A1 - General Economics > A10 - General |
Item ID: | 3701 |
Depositing User: | patrizia sbriglia |
Date Deposited: | 25 Jun 2007 |
Last Modified: | 02 Oct 2019 04:11 |
References: | Akerlof G.A. and R.E. Kranton (2000), “Economics and Indentity”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115: 715-53. Alesina A. and E. La Ferrara (2005), “Ethnic Diversity and Economic Performance”, Journal of Economic Literature, 63: 762-800. Aumann R. (1995), “Backward Induction and Common Knowledge of Rationality”, Games and Economic Behaviour, 8, 6-19. Aumann R. (1996), “Reply to Binmore”, Games and Economic Behaviour, 17, 135-137. Aumann R.J. (1998), “On the Centipede Game”, Games and Economic Behavior 23: 97-105. Barr A., M Lindelow., J. Garcia-Montalvo, P. Serneels (2005), “Strategy Choice and Cognitive Ability in Field Experiments”, GPRG – WPS - 034. Binmore K. (1988) “Modeling rational players: I, II”, Economics and Philosophy, 3: 179- 214; 4, 9-55. Benabou R. and J. Tirole (2004), “Incentives and prosocial behaviour”, Princeton University, mimeo. Binmore K. (1996), “A Note on Backward Induction”, Games and Economic Behaviour, 17, 135-137. Burlando R. M., F. Guala (2005), “Heterogeneous Agents in Public Good Experiments”, Experimental Economics, 8: 35-54. Elster J. (1989), “Social Norms and Economic Theory”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3: 99-117. Falk A., Fehr E. and U. Fischbacher (2003), “On the nature of fair behaviour”, Economic Inquiry, 41: 20-6. Fehr E. and U. Fischbacher (2002), “Why Social Preferences Matter – The Impact of Non-Selfish Motives on Competition, Cooperation and Incentives”, Economic Journal, C1-C33. Fehr E. and K.M. Schmidt (1999), “A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114: 816-818. Fehr E. and K.M. Schmidt (2006), “Experimental Evidence and New Theories”, in S-C. Kolm and J.M. Ythier (eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, Vol. I, North-Holland, Amsterdam. Fey, M., R.D. McKelvey, and T.R. Palfrey (1996), “An Experimental Study of Constant-Sum Centipede Games”, International Journal of Game Theory, 25: 269-87. Fischbacher U., S. Gachter, and E. Fehr (2001), “Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment”, Economic Letters, 397-404. Gachter S. and C. Thoni (2005), “Social learning and voluntary cooperation among like-minded people”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 3: 303-14. Güth, W., S. Huck, W. Mueller (2001) “The relevance of equal split in ultimatum games”, Games and Economic Behaviour, 37: 161-69. Habyarimana J., M. Humphries, D.N. Posner, and J.M. Weinstein (2007), “Why Does Ethnic Diversity Undermine Public Goods Provision?”, University of California at Los Angeles, mimeo. Levine D. (1998), “Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments”, Review of Economic Dynamics, 1, 593-622. McKelvey R.D. and T. R. Palfrey (1992), “An Experimental Study of the Centipede Game”, Econometrica, 60, 803-836. Nagel R. and F.F. Tang (1998), “Experimental Results on the Centipede Game in Normal Form: an investigation on learning”, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 42: 356-384. Nagel T. (1970), The Possibility of Altruism, Clarendon Press, Oxford. Ponti G. (2000), “Cycles of Learning in the Centipede Game”, Games and Economic Behavior 20: 115-141. Rabin M. (1993), “Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics”, American Economic Review, 83, 1281-1302. Reny P. (1992), “Rationality in extensive-form games”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6, 105-18. Rosenthal R. (1981), “Games of Perfect Information, Predatory Pricing, and the Chain-store Paradox”, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 25, 92-100. Selten R. (1967), “Die Strategiemethode zur erforschung des eingeschränkt rationalen verhaltens in rahmen eimes oligopolexperiments” in Sauerman, H. (ed) Beiträge Zur Experimentallen Wirtschaftsforschung, Tübingen: J.C.B., Mohr (Paul Siebeck). Selten R. (1975), “Reexamination of the Perfectness Concept for Equilibrium Points in Extensive Games”, International Journal of Game Theory, 4, 25-55. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/3701 |