Igan, Deniz and Pinheiro, Marcelo (2012): The effects of relative performance objectives on financial markets.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_43452.pdf Download (641kB) | Preview |
Abstract
We analyze the implications of linking the compensation of fund managers to the return of their portfolio relative to that of a benchmark. In the presence of such relative-performance-based objectives, investors have reduced expected utility but markets are typically more informative and deeper. Furthermore, in a multiple asset/market framework we show that (i) relative performance concerns lead to an increase in the correlation between markets (financial contagion); (ii) benchmark inclusion leads to increases in price volatility; (iii) home bias emerges as a rational outcome. Finally, when information is costly, information acquisition is hindered and this attenuates the effects on informativeness and depth of the market.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | The effects of relative performance objectives on financial markets |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Delegated portfolio management, Informativeness, Liquidity, Contagion, Home bias |
Subjects: | G - Financial Economics > G1 - General Financial Markets > G11 - Portfolio Choice ; Investment Decisions G - Financial Economics > G2 - Financial Institutions and Services > G23 - Non-bank Financial Institutions ; Financial Instruments ; Institutional Investors |
Item ID: | 43452 |
Depositing User: | Deniz Igan |
Date Deposited: | 27 Dec 2012 16:36 |
Last Modified: | 27 Sep 2019 05:04 |
References: | Admati, A.R., and P. Pfleiderer (1997). “Does It All Add Up? Benchmarks and the Compensation of Active Portfolio Managers,” Journal of Business 70, 323-350. Bagnoli, M., and S. Watts (2000). “Chasing Hot Funds: The Effects of Relative Performance on Portfolio Choice,” Financial Management 29 (3), 31-50. Benartzi, S., and R. Thaler (2001). “Naive Diversification Strategies in Retirement Saving Plans,” American Economic Review 91, 79-98. Berk, J. B., and R. C. Green (2004). “Mutual Fund Flows and Performance in Rational Markets,” Journal of Political Economy 112 (6), 1269-1295. Brennan, M. J. (1993). “Agency and Asset Pricing”, working paper, UCLA. Brown, K., W. Harlow, and L. Starks (1996). “Of Tournaments and Temptations: An Analysis of Managerial Incentives in the Mutual Fund Industry,” Journal of Finance 51, 85-110. Chen, H.-L., and G. Pennacchi (2009). “Does Prior Performance Affect a Mutual Fund’s Choice of Risk? Theory and Further Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 44 (4), 745-775. Chevalier, J., and G. Ellison (1997). “Risk Taking by Mutual Funds as a Response to Incentives,” Journal of Political Economy 105, 1167-1200. Coval, J., and T.Moskowitz (1999). “Home Bias at Home: Local Equity Preference in Domestic Portfolios,” Journal of Finance 54 (5), 2045-2074. Cuoco, D., and R. Kaniel (2011). “Equilibrium Prices in the Presence of Delegated Portfolio Management,” Journal of Financial Economics 101, 264-269. Das, S., and R. Sundaram (1998a). “On the Regulation of Mutual Fund Fee Structures,” NBER Working Paper 6639. Das, S., and R. Sundaram (1998b). “Fee Speech: Adverse Selection and the Regulation of Mutual Fund Fees,” NBER Working Paper 6644. Dybvig, P., H. Farnsworth, and J. Carpenter (2010). “Portfolio Performance and Agency,” Review of Financial Studies 23 (1), 1-23. Eichberger, J., S. Grant, and S. P. King (1999). “On Relative Performance Contracts and Fund Manager’s Incentives,” European Economic Review 43, 135-161. Goriaev, A., F. Palomino, and A. Prat (2000). “Mutual Fund Tournament: Risk Taking Incentives Induced By Ranking Objectives,” Working Paper CentER, Tilburg University, No 2000-94. Grinblatt, M., and S. Titman (1989). “Adverse Risk Incentives and the Design of Performance Based Contracts,” Management Science 35, 807-822. Heinkel, R., and N. M. Stoughton (1994). “The Dynamics of Portfolio Management Contracts,” Review of Financial Studies 7, 351-387. Koski, J., and J. Pontiff (1999). “How are Derivatives Used: Evidence from the Mutual Fund Industry,” Journal of Finance 54 (2), 791-816. Ippolito, R. A. (1992). “Consumer Reaction to Measures of Poor Quality: Evidence from the Mutual Fund Industry,” Journal of Law and Economics 35, 45-70. Kyle, P. (1985). “Continuous Auction and Insider Trading,” Econometrica 53 (6), 1315-1336. Lettau, M. (1997). “Explaining the Facts with Adaptative Agents: The Case of Mutual Fund Flows,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 21, 1117-1147. Ou-Yang, H. (2003). “Optimal Contracts in a Continuous-Time Delegated Portfolio Management Problem,” Review of Financial Studies 16, 173 - 208. Palomino, F. (2005). “Relative Performance Objectives in Financial Markets,” Journal of Financial Intermediation 14, 351-375. Pinheiro, M., (2008). “Loyalty, peer group effects, and 401(k),” Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 48(1), 94-122. Sensoy, B. (2009). “Performance evaluation and self-designated benchmark indexes in the mutual fund industry,” Journal of Financial Economics 92 (1), 25—39. Sirri, E. R., and P. Tufano (1998). “Costly Search and Mutual Fund Flows,” Journal of Finance 53, 1589-1622. Starks, L. T. (1987). “Performance Incentive Fees: An Agency Theoretic Approach,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 22, 17-32. Taylor, J. (2003). “Risk-Taking Behavior in Mutual Fund Tournaments,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 50 (3), 373-83. Tesar, L., and I. Werner (1995). “Home Bias and High Turnover,” Journal of International Money and Finance 14 (4), 467-492. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/43452 |