Roncaglia, Alesandro (2015): ¿Debería la Historia del Pensamiento Económico ser incluida en los Planes de Estudio de Economía en Pregrado? Published in: Borradores Departamento de Economia No. # 55 (30 June 2015): pp. 1-18.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_67384.pdf Download (689kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Mainstream views concerning the uselessness or usefulness of HET are illustrated. These rely on a hidden assumption: a ‘cumulative view’ according to which the provisional point of arrival of contemporary economics incorporates all previous contributions in an improved way. Critiques of positivism led philosophy of science to recognise the existence of different approaches – in economics, as in other sciences. Conceptualisation, recognised by Schumpeter as the first stage in economic theorising, is the stage in which the different visions of the world underlying the different approaches, take shape – and are better recognised. In this, HET plays an essential role. As an illustration, the differences between the classical and marginalist conceptualisations of the economy are illustrated. Thus HET is essential in both undergraduate and graduate economic curricula, as a decisive help towards a better understanding and evaluation of formalised theories/models in the first case, and as an education to the philological method of research, essential in the first stage of theorising, in the case of graduate curricula
Resumen: Este artículo discute los puntos de vista de la corriente de pensamiento dominante respecto a la utilidad o inutilidad de la Historia del Pensamiento Económico (en adelante HPE). Estos puntos de vista se basan en un supuesto oculto: una “visión acumulativa” según la cual el punto de llegada provisional de la economía contemporánea debe incorporar todas las contribuciones teóricas anteriores de una forma mejorada. Los críticos del positivismo le permitieron a la filosofía de la ciencia reconocer la existencia de diferentes enfoques, tanto en la economía como en otras ciencias. La conceptualización, reconocida por Schumpeter como la primera etapa en la teorización económica, permite que las diferentes visiones del mundo en las cuales se basan los diversos enfoques, tomen forma y alcancen un mayor reconocimiento. Es aquí donde la HPE juega un papel esencial. En este artículo se toma como ejemplo las diferencias entre los enfoques clásicos y marginalistas de la Economía. De esta forma, la HPE resulta esencial en los Planes de Estudio de Economía tanto a nivel de pregrado como de posgrado. En el primer caso como una ayuda decisiva para una mejor comprensión y evaluación de los teorías/modelos ya formalizados y, en el segundo caso, como una formación en el método filológico de investigación, esencial en la primera etapa de la teorización.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | ¿Debería la Historia del Pensamiento Económico ser incluida en los Planes de Estudio de Economía en Pregrado? |
English Title: | Should the History of Economic Thought be Included in Undergraduate Curricula? |
Language: | Spanish |
Keywords: | history of economic analysis, undergraduate curricula, graduate curricula, heterodox approaches, stages of economic theorising. Historia del análisis económico, Planes de estudios de Economía de pregrado, Planes de estudios de Economía de posgrado, Enfoques heterodoxos, Etapas de la teorización económica. |
Subjects: | A - General Economics and Teaching > A2 - Economic Education and Teaching of Economics > A20 - General B - History of Economic Thought, Methodology, and Heterodox Approaches > B3 - History of Economic Thought: Individuals > B30 - General |
Item ID: | 67384 |
Depositing User: | Laura Maria Posada Arboleda |
Date Deposited: | 23 Oct 2015 13:01 |
Last Modified: | 27 Sep 2019 14:10 |
References: | Blaug, M. (2001) ‘No history of ideas, please, we’re economists’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, pp. 145-64. Caldwell, B. (2013) ‘Of positivism and the history of economic thought’, Southern Economic Journal, 79, pp. 753-67. Gordon, D. (1965) ‘The role of the history of economic thought in the understanding of modern economic theory’, American Economic Review, 55, pp. 119-27. Harcourt, G.C. (1972) Some Cambridge controversies in the theory of capital (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Hicks, J. (1969) A theory of economic history (Oxford: Oxford University Press). Hollander, J. (1904) ‘The development of Ricardo’s theory of value’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 18, pp. 455-91. Hollander, J. (1910) David Ricardo - A centenary estimate (Baltimore; repr. New York: McKelley, 1968). Hollander, S. (1973) The economics of Adam Smith (Toronto: University of Toronto Press). Hollander, S. (1979) The economics of David Ricardo (Toronto: University of Toronto Press). Keynes, J.M. (1973) The General Theory and after, in Collected writings, vols. 13 (Part I: preparation) and 14 (Part II: defense and development), ed. by D. Moggridge (London: Macmillan). Kates, S. (2013) Defending the history of economic thought (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar). Kula, W. [1958]. Riflessioni sulla storia. Venezia: Marsilio, 1990 (English translation, The problems and methods of economic history, (Aldershot: Ashgate) 2001). Marcuzzo, M. C. (2008) ‘Is history of economic thought a “serious” subject?’, Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics, 1, pp. 107-23. Marcuzzo, M. C. and Rosselli, A. (2002) ‘Economics as history of economics: the Italian case in retrospect’, in Weintraub (ed.), pp. 98-109. Mill, J.S.(1863/1987) Utilitarianism, reprinted in Mill J.S. and Bentham, J., Utilitarianism and other essays, ed. by A. Ryan (London: Penguin Books). Roncaglia, A. (1996) ‘Why should economists study the history of economic thought?’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 3, pp. 296-309. Roncaglia, A. (2005) The wealth of ideas (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Traducción Española: La riqueza de las ideas: Una historia del pensamiento económico, Prensas Universitarias de Zaragoza, 2006. Roncaglia, A. (2009) ‘Keynes and probability: an assessment’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 16, pp. 489-510. Roncaglia, A. (2010) ‘The origins of social inequality: beavers for women, deer for men’, in A. Birolo, D. Foley, H. Kurz, B. Schefold, I. Steedman (eds), Production, distribution and trade: alternative perspectives. Essays in honour of Sergio Parrinello (London: Routledge), pp. 289-303. Samuelson, P.A. (1947) Foundations of economic analysis. (Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press). Schabas, M. (1992) ‘Breaking away: history of economics as history of science’, History of Political Economy, 24, pp. 187-203. Schumpeter, J. (1954) History of economic analysis, ed. by E. Boody Schumpeter (New York: Oxford University Press). Sraffa, P. (1951) ‘Introduction’, in Ricardo D., Works and correspondence, 10 vols., ed. by P. Sraffa, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1951-55, vol. I, pp. xiii-lxii. Sraffa, P. (1960) Production of commodities by means of commodities (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). Viner, J. (1991) Essays on the intellectual history of economics, ed. by D.A. Irwin (Princeton: Princeton University Press). Weintraub, R. (ed.) (2002) The future of the history of economics. Annual Supplement, History of Political Economy, 34. Weintraub, R. (2002) ‘Will economics ever have a past again?’, in Weintraub (ed.), pp. 1-14. Cita sugerida: Roncaglia, A. (2014) ‘Should the History of Economic Thought be Included in Undergraduate Curricula?’. Economic Thought, 3.1, pp. 1-9. http://www.worldeconomicsassociation.org/files /journals/economicthought/WEA-ET-3-1-Roncaglia.pdf |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/67384 |