Nóbrega, Valter (2020): Optimal Taxation and Investment-Specific Technological Change.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_98917.pdf Download (440kB) | Preview |
Abstract
In this paper, we look at the relationship between Investment Specific Technological Change (ISTC) and optimal level of labor income progressivity. We develop an incomplete markets overlapping generations model that matches relevant features of the US economy and find that the observed drop in the relative price of investment since the 1980's leads optimal progressivity to increase. This result hinges on ISTC increasing the wage premium through an increase in the variance of the permanent component of labor income. This result is supported by recent findings in the literature that highlight the increasing role of the permanent component of labor income in the observed increase in income inequality.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Optimal Taxation and Investment-Specific Technological Change |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Optimal taxation; Technological Change; Income Inequality |
Subjects: | E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy > E21 - Consumption ; Saving ; Wealth H - Public Economics > H2 - Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue > H21 - Efficiency ; Optimal Taxation J - Labor and Demographic Economics > J0 - General |
Item ID: | 98917 |
Depositing User: | Valter Nóbrega |
Date Deposited: | 06 Mar 2020 16:56 |
Last Modified: | 06 Mar 2020 16:56 |
References: | Acemoglu, D., and Autor, D. (2011). Skills, tasks and technologies: Implications for employment and earnings. In Handbook of labor economics (Vol. 4, pp. 1043-1171). Elsevier. Acemoglu, D., and Restrepo, P. (2018). Low-skill and high-skill automation. Journal of Human Capital, 12(2), 204-232. Acemoglu, D. (2002). Technical change, inequality, and the labor market. Journal of economic literature, 40(1), 7-72. Aiyagari, S. R. (1994). Uninsured idiosyncratic risk and aggregate saving. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(3), 659-684. Autor, D. H., Levy, F., and Murnane, R. J. (2003). The skill content of recent technological change: An empirical exploration. The Quarterly journal of economics, 118(4), 1279-1333. Benabou, R. (2002). Tax and education policy in a heterogeneous‐agent economy: What levels of redistribution maximize growth and efficiency?. Econometrica, 70(2), 481-517. Bewley, T. F. (2000). Has the Decline in the Price of Investment Increased Wealth Inequality?. Unpublished. Brinca, P., Oliveira, J., and Duarte, J. (2019). Investment-Specific Technological Change, Taxation and Inequality in the US. Brinca, P., Faria-e-Castro, M., Homem Ferreira, M., and Holter, H. (2019). The nonlinear effects of fiscal policy. FRB St. Louis Working Paper, (2019-15). Brinca, P., Holter, H. A., Krusell, P., and Malafry, L. (2016). Fiscal multipliers in the 21st century. Journal of Monetary Economics, 77, 53-69. Brinca, P., Homem Ferreira, M., Franco, F. A., Holter, H. A., and Malafry, L. (2019). Fiscal consolidation programs and income inequality. Conesa, J. C., and Krueger, D. (2006). On the optimal progressivity of the income tax code. Journal of Monetary Economics, 53(7), 1425-1450. Conesa, J. C., Kitao, S., and Krueger, D. (2009). Taxing capital? Not a bad idea after all!. American Economic Review, 99(1), 25-48. Eden, M. and Gaggl, P. (2018). On the welfare implications of automation. Review of Economic Dynamics, 29. Ferreira, A. M. (2019). Skill-Biased Technological Change and Inequality in the US. Ferriere, A., and Navarro, G. (2014). The heterogeneous effects of government spending: It's all about taxes. Gouveia, M., and Strauss, R. P. (1994). Effective federal individual income tax functions: An exploratory empirical analysis. National Tax Journal, 317-339. Heathcote, J., Storesletten, K., and Violante, G. L. (2017). Optimal tax progressivity: An analytical framework. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132(4), 1693-1754. Huggett, M., Ventura, G., and Yaron, A. (2011). Sources of lifetime inequality. American Economic Review, 101(7), 2923-54. Huggett, M. (1993). The risk-free rate in heterogeneous-agent incomplete-insurance economies. Journal of economic Dynamics and Control, 17(5-6), 953-969. Karabarbounis, L., and Neiman, B. (2014). The global decline of the labor share. The Quarterly journal of economics, 129(1), 61-103. Krusell, P., Ohanian, L. E., Ríos-Rull, J.-V., and Violante, G. L. (2000). Capital-skill complemen- tarity and inequality: A macroeconomic analysis. Econometrica, 68(5). Mankiw, N. G., Weinzierl, M., and Yagan, D. (2009). Optimal taxation in theory and practice. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(4), 147-74. Mendoza, E. G., Razin, A., and Tesar, L. L. (1994). Effective tax rates in macroeconomics: Cross-country estimates of tax rates on factor incomes and consumption. Journal of Monetary Economics, 34(3), 297-323. Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. The review of economic studies, 38(2), 175-208. Nordhaus, W. D. (2007). Two centuries of productivity growth in computing. The Journal of Economic History, 67(1), 128-159. Ramsey, F. P. (1927). A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation. The Economic Journal, 37(145), 47-61. Saez, E. (2001). Using elasticities to derive optimal income tax rates. The review of economic studies, 68(1), 205-229. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/98917 |