Bhatt, Vipul and Kishor, N. Kundan (2023): (In)Stability of the relationship between relative expenditure and prices of durable and non-durable goods.
Preview |
PDF
Durables_VB_April172023.pdf Download (383kB) | Preview |
Abstract
This study shows that, in a model with non-separable preferences for durable and non-durable goods, the effect of relative prices on the ratio of consumption for the two goods, known as the intratemporal elasticity of substitution, has decreased in the U.S. since 1981. We found that durable and non-durable goods were gross substitutes until 1981 and have been gross complements in the period after that. This break also had significant implications for short-term consumption dynamics. Although durable goods still drive most of the adjustment towards long-term equilibrium in non-durables, durables, and relative prices, the size of the adjustment has significantly decreased in the post-1981 period, suggesting slower convergence towards long-run equilibrium. Additionally, we found that the durable goods cycle has become more persistent over time. During the recent pandemic, durable goods were more than 20% above the long-term common trend that they share with non-durable goods and their relative prices. The findings of this study also have implications for the global supply chain pressures that have contributed to rapid inflation in the post-COVID period. The estimated durable goods cycle and the Global Supply Chain Pressure Index exhibit a non-linear relationship, where a deviation of more than 4.8% from the long-term common trend leads to a significant increase in the supply chain pressure index.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | (In)Stability of the relationship between relative expenditure and prices of durable and non-durable goods |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Durable Goods Consumption, Intratemportal Elasticity of Substitution, Structural Break, Trend Cycle Decomposition. |
Subjects: | E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy > E21 - Consumption ; Saving ; Wealth E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy > E23 - Production E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E3 - Prices, Business Fluctuations, and Cycles > E32 - Business Fluctuations ; Cycles E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E5 - Monetary Policy, Central Banking, and the Supply of Money and Credit > E52 - Monetary Policy |
Item ID: | 117688 |
Depositing User: | N Kundan Kishor |
Date Deposited: | 20 Jun 2023 13:57 |
Last Modified: | 20 Jun 2023 13:57 |
References: | Ando, A., & Modigliani, F. (1963). The life cycle hypothesis of saving: Aggregate implications and tests. The American economic review, 53(1), 55-84. Arai, Y., & Kurozumi, E. (2007). Testing for the null hypothesis of cointegration with a structural break. Econometric Reviews, 26(6), 705-739. Atkeson, A., & Ogaki, M. (1996). Wealth-varying intertemporal elasticities of substitution: Evidence from panel and aggregate data. Journal of monetary Economics, 38(3), 507-534. Bai, J., & Perron, P. (1998). Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural changes. Econometrica, 47-78. Bernanke, Ben (2003), "'Constrained Discretion,' and Monetary Policy," Remarks Before the Money Marketeers of New York University, New York, New York, February 3, 2003. Beveridge, S., & Nelson, C. R. (1981). A new approach to decomposition of economic time series into permanent and transitory components with particular attention to measurement of the `business cycle'. Journal of Monetary economics, 7(2), 151-174. Bhatt, V., Kundan Kishor, N., & Marfatia, H. (2020). Estimating Excess Sensitivity and Habit Persistence in Consumption Using Greenbook Forecasts. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 82(2), 257-284. Dynan, K. E., Elmendorf, D. W., & Sichel, D. E. (2006). Can financial innovation help to explain the reduced volatility of economic activity?. Journal of monetary Economics, 53(1), 123-150. Engle, Robert and Clive W.J. Granger (1987). "Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing." Econometrica, 55(2): 251-275. Favero, C. A. (2001). Applied macroeconometrics. Oxford University Press. Friedman, M. (1957). The permanent income hypothesis. In A theory of the consumption function (pp. 20-37). Princeton University Press. Hall, R. E. (1978). Stochastic implications of the life cycle-permanent income hypothesis: theory and evidence. Journal of political economy, 86(6), 971-987. Hall, R. E. (1988). Intertemporal substitution in consumption. Journal of political economy, 96(2), 339-357. Hall, R. E. (2011). The long slump. American Economic Review, 101(2), 431-69. Hansen, B. E. (2000). Sample splitting and threshold estimation. Econometrica, 68(3), 575-603. Hansen, B. E. (2011). Threshold autoregression in economics. Statistics and its Interface, 4(2), 123-127. Hansen, L. P., & Singleton, K. J. (1996). Efficient estimation of linear asset-pricing models with moving average errors. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 14(1), 53-68. Hymans, S. H., Ackley, G., & Juster, F. T. (1970). Consumer durable spending: explanation and prediction. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1970(2), 173-206. Kejriwal, M. (2008). Cointegration with structural breaks: An application to the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle. Studies in nonlinear dynamics & econometrics, 12(1). Kejriwal, M., & Perron, P. (2010). Testing for multiple structural changes in cointegrated regression models. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 28(4), 503-522. Kim, C. J., & Nelson, C. R. (1999). Has the US economy become more stable? A Bayesian approach based on a Markov-switching model of the business cycle. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(4), 608-616. LaBelle, J., & Santacreu, A. M. (2022). Global supply chain disruptions and inflation during the COVID-19 pandemic. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review. Leamer, E. E. (2007). Housing is the business cycle. NBER Working Paper. Leamer, E. E. (2009). Homes and cars: Why are the cycles in homes and consumer durables so similar?. The BE Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 9(3). Levy, D. and Chen, H. (1994), Estimates of the aggregate quarterly capital stock for the post-war U.S. economy. Review of Income and Wealth, 40: 317-349. Mankiw, N. G. (1982). Hall's consumption hypothesis and durable goods. Journal of Monetary Economics, 10(3), 417-425. McConnell, M. M., & Perez-Quiros, G. (2000). Output fluctuations in the United States: What has changed since the early 1980's?. American Economic Review, 90(5), 1464-1476. McKay, A., & Wieland, J. F. (2021). Lumpy durable consumption demand and the limited ammunition of monetary policy. Econometrica, 89(6), 2717-2749. Morley, J. C. (2002). A state--space approach to calculating the Beveridge--Nelson decomposition. Economics Letters, 75(1), 123-127. Ogaki, M., & Reinhart, C. M. (1998). Measuring intertemporal substitution: The role of durable goods. Journal of political Economy, 106(5), 1078-1098. Okubo, M. (2003). Intratemporal substitution between private and government consumption: the case of Japan. Economics Letters, 79(1), 75-81. Okubo, M. (2008). On the intertemporal elasticity of substitution under nonhomothetic utility. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40(5), 1065-1072. Pakoš, M. (2011). Estimating intertemporal and intratemporal substitutions when both income and substitution effects are present: the role of durable goods. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 29(3), 439-454. Power, J. (2004). Durable spending, relative prices and consumption. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Spring. Startz, R. (1989). The stochastic behavior of durable and nondurable consumption. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 356-363. Van Zandweghe, W., & Braxton, J. C. (2013). Has durable goods spending become less sensitive to interest rates?. Economic Review-Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 5. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/117688 |