Duffy, Sean and Smith, John (2020): An economist and a psychologist form a line: What can imperfect perception of length tell us about stochastic choice?
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_99417.pdf Download (258kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Standard choice experiments are hampered by the fact that utility is either unknown or imperfectly measured by experimenters. As a consequence, the inferences available to researchers are limited. By contrast, we design a choice experiment where the objects are valued according to only a single attribute with a continuous measure and we can observe the true preferences of subjects. Subjects have an imperfect perception of the choice objects but can improve the precision of their perception with cognitive effort. Subjects are given a choice set involving several lines of various lengths and are told to select one of them. They strive to select the longest line because they are paid an amount that increases with the length of their choice. Our design allows us to observe the search history, the response times, and make unambiguous conclusions about the optimality of choices. We find a negative relationship between the demanding nature of the choice problems and the likelihood that subjects select the optimal lines. We also find a positive relationship between the demanding nature of the choice problems and the response times. However, we find evidence that suboptimal choices are associated with longer response times than are optimal choices. This result appears to be consistent with Fudenberg, Strack, and Strzalecki (2018). Additionally, our experimental design permits a multinomial discrete choice analysis. Our results suggest that the errors in our data are better described as having a Gumbel distribution rather than a normal distribution. We also observe effects consistent with memory decay and attention. Finally, we find evidence that choices in our experiment exhibit the independence from irrelevant alternatives (IIA) property.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | An economist and a psychologist form a line: What can imperfect perception of length tell us about stochastic choice? |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | judgment, memory, response times, independence from irrelevant alternatives |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C9 - Design of Experiments > C91 - Laboratory, Individual Behavior D - Microeconomics > D0 - General > D03 - Behavioral Microeconomics: Underlying Principles |
Item ID: | 99417 |
Depositing User: | John Smith |
Date Deposited: | 07 Apr 2020 14:10 |
Last Modified: | 07 Apr 2020 14:10 |
References: | Achtziger, Anja and Alós-Ferrer, Carlos (2014): "Fast or rational? A response-times study of Bayesian updating," Management Science, 60(4), 923--938. Agranov, Marina and Ortoleva, Pietro (2017): "Stochastic choice and preferences for randomization," Journal of Political Economy, 125(1), 40--68. Aguiar, Victor H., Boccardi, Maria Jose, and Dean, Mark (2016): "Satisficing and stochastic choice," Journal of Economic Theory, 166, 445--482. Ahn, David S. and Sarver, Todd (2013): "Preference for flexibility and random choice," Econometrica, 81(1), 341--361. Ahumada, Alonso and Ulku, Levent (2018): "Luce rule with limited consideration," Mathematical Social Sciences, 93, 52--56. Akaike, Hirotugu (1974): "A new look at the statistical model identification," IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, 19(6), 716--723. Alós-Ferrer, Carlos, Fehr, Ernst, and Netzer, Nick (2018): "Time will tell: recovering preferences when choices are noisy," Working paper, University of Zurich. Alós-Ferrer, Carlos and Garagnani, Michele (2019): "Strength of preference and decision making under risk," Working paper, University of Zurich. Alós-Ferrer, Carlos, Granić, Đura-Georg, Kern, Johannes, and Wagner, Alexander K. (2016): "Preference reversals: Time and again," Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 52(1), 65--97. Apesteguia, Jose and Ballester, Miguel A. (2018): "Monotone stochastic choice models: The case of risk and time preferences," Journal of Political Economy, 126(1), 74--106. Apesteguia, Jose, Ballester, Miguel A., and Lu, Jay (2017): "Single-Crossing Random Utility Models," Econometrica, 85(2), 661--674. Argenziano, Rossella and Gilboa, Itzhak (2017): "Psychophysical foundations of the Cobb--Douglas utility function," Economics Letters, 157, 21--23. Armel, K. Carrie, Beaumel, Aurelie, and Rangel, Antonio (2008): "Biasing simple choices by manipulating relative visual attention," Judgment and Decision Making, 3(5), 396--403. Armel, K. Carrie and Rangel, Antonio (2008): "The Impact of Computation Time and Experience on Decision Values," American Economic Review, 98(2), 163--168. Ballinger, T. Parker, and Wilcox, Nathaniel T. (1997): "Decisions, Error and Heterogeneity," Economic Journal, 107(443), 1090--1105. Becker, Gordon M., DeGroot, Morris H., and Marschak, Jacob (1963): "Stochastic models of choice behavior," Systems Research and Behavioral Science, 8(1), 41--55. Bhui, Rahul (2019a): "A statistical test for the optimality of deliberative time allocation," Psychonomic Bulletin and Review, 26(3), 855--867. Bhui, Rahul (2019b): "Testing Optimal Timing in Value-Linked Decision Making," Computational Brain and Behavior, 2(2), 85--94. Blavatskyy, Pavlo R. (2008): "Stochastic utility theorem," Journal of Mathematical Economics, 44, 1049--1056. Blavatskyy, Pavlo R. (2011): "Probabilistic risk aversion with an arbitrary outcome set," Economics Letters, 112(1), 34--37. Bradley, Ralph Allan and Terry, Milton E. (1952): "Rank analysis of incomplete block designs: I. The method of paired comparisons," Biometrika, 39(3-4), 324--345. Butler, David J. (2000): "Do non-expected utility choice patterns spring from hazy preferences? An experimental study of choice `errors'," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 41(3), 277--297. Butler, David and Loomes, Graham (1988): "Decision difficulty and imprecise preferences," Acta Psychologica, 68(1-3), 183--196. Butler, David J. and Loomes, Graham C. (2007): "Imprecision as an account of the preference reversal phenomenon," American Economic Review, 97(1), 277--297. Caplin, Andrew (2012): "Choice Sets as Percepts," In Neuroscience of Preference and Choice: Cognitive and Neural Mechanisms, Dolan, Raymond and Sharot, Tali (Eds.), Academic Press, Waltham MA, 295--304. Caplin, Andrew, Csaba, Daniel, Leahy, John, and Nov, Oded (2018): "Rational Inattention, Competitive Supply, and Psychometrics," Working paper, New York University. Caplin, Andrew and Dean, Mark (2015): "Revealed preference, rational inattention, and costly information acquisition," American Economic Review, 105(7), 2183--2203. Caplin, Andrew, Dean, Mark, and Leahy, John (2019): "Rationally Inattentive Behavior: Characterizing and Generalizing Shannon Entropy," Working Paper, Columbia University. Caplin, Andrew, Dean, Mark, and Martin, Daniel (2011): "Search and satisficing," American Economic Review, 101(7), 2899--2922. Caplin, Andrew and Martin, Daniel (2015): "A testable theory of imperfect perception," Economic Journal, 125(582), 184--202. Cattaneo, Matias D., Ma, Xinwei, Masatlioglu, Yusufcan, and Suleymanov, Elchin (2019): "A Random Attention Model," Journal of Political Economy, forthcoming. Cerreia-Vioglio, Simone, Dillenberger, David, Ortoleva, Pietro, and Riella, Gil (2019): "Deliberately stochastic," American Economic Review, 109(7), 2425--2445. Chen, Fadong and Fischbacher, Urs (2016): "Response time and click position: Cheap indicators of preferences," Journal of the Economic Science Association, 2(2), 109--126. Clithero, John A. (2018): "Response times in economics: Looking through the lens of sequential sampling models," Journal of Economic Psychology, 69, 61--86. Conte, Anna and Hey, John D. (2019): "Rehabilitating the Random Utility Model. A comment on Apesteguia and Ballester (2018)," Working paper, Univerity of York. Conte, Anna, Hey, John D., and Moffatt, Peter G. (2011): "Mixture models of choice under risk," Journal of Econometrics, 162(1), 79--88. Cubitt, Robin P., Navarro-Martinez, Daniel, and Starmer, Chris (2015): "On preference imprecision," Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 50(1), 1--34. Dashiell, John Frederick (1937): "Affective value-distances as a determinant of esthetic judgment-times," American Journal of Psychology, 50(1/4), 57--67. Dean, Mark and Neligh, Nathaniel (2017): "Experimental Tests of Rational Inattention," Working Paper, Columbia University. Debreu, Gerard (1958): "Stochastic choice and cardinal utility," Econometrica, 26(3), 440--444. Duffy, Sean, Gussman, Steven, and Smith, John (2019): "Judgments of length in the economics laboratory: Are there brains in choice?" Working paper, Rutgers University-Camden. Dutilh, Gilles and Rieskamp, Jörg (2016): "Comparing perceptual and preferential decision making," Psychonomic Bulletin and Review, 23(3), 723--737. Echenique, Federico, Saito, Kota, and Tserenjigmid, Gerelt (2018): "The perception-adjusted Luce model," Mathematical Social Sciences, 93, 67--76. Echenique, Federico and Saito, Kota (2017): "Response time and utility," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 139, 49--59. Falmagne, J. C. (1978): "A representation theorem for finite random scale systems," Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 18(1), 52--72. Fechner, Gustav Theodor (1860): Elemente der Psychophysik. (Elements of psychophysics, translated 1966. Holt, Rinehart, and Winston, New York.) Frederick, Shane (2005): "Cognitive reflection and decision making," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4), 25--42. Fudenberg, Drew, Iijima, Ryota, and Strzalecki, Tomasz (2015): "Stochastic choice and revealed perturbed utility," Econometrica, 83(6), 2371--2409. Fudenberg, Drew, Strack, Philipp, and Strzalecki, Tomasz (2018): "Speed, accuracy, and the optimal timing of choices," American Economic Review, 108(12), 3651--3684. Gabaix, Xavier, Laibson, David, Moloche, Guillermo, and Weinberg, Stephen (2006): "Costly information acquisition: Experimental analysis of a boundedly rational model," American Economic Review, 96(4), 1043--1068. Gul, Faruk, Natenzon, Paulo, and Pesendorfer, Wolfgang (2014): "Random choice as behavioral optimization," Econometrica, 82(5), 1873--1912. Gul, Faruk and Pesendorfer, Wolfgang (2006): "Random expected utility," Econometrica, 74(1), 121--146. Henmon, V. A. C. (1911): "The relation of the time of a judgment to its accuracy," Psychological Review, 18(3), 186--201. Hey, John D. (1995): "Experimental investigations of errors in decision making under risk," European Economic Review, 39(3-4), 633--640. Horan, Sean, Manzini, Paola, and Mariotti, Marco (2019): "When Is Coarseness Not a Curse? The Comparative Statics of Coarse Perception in Choice," Working paper, University of Montreal. Jamieson, Donald G. and Petrusic, William M. (1977): "Preference and the time to choose," Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 19(1), 56--67. Kellogg, W. N. (1931): "The time of judgment in psychometric measures," American Journal of Psychology, 43(1), 65--86. Khaw, Mel Win, Li, Ziang, and Woodford, Michael (2017): "Risk aversion as a perceptual bias," Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research. Kiss, Hubert Janos, Rodriguez-Lara, Ismael, and Rosa-Garcia, Alfonso (2020): "Does response time predict withdrawal decisions? Lessons from a bank-run experiment," Review of Behavioral Finance, forthcoming. Koida, Nobuo (2018): "Anticipated stochastic choice," Economic Theory, 65(3), 545--574. Konovalov, Arkady and Krajbich, Ian (2019): "Revealed strength of preference: Inference from response times," Judgment and Decision Making, 14(4), 381--394. Kovach, Matthew and Tserenjigmid, Gerelt (2018): "The focal Luce model," Working paper Virginia Tech. Krajbich, Ian, Armel, Carrie, and Rangel, Antonio (2010): "Visual fixations and the computation and comparison of value in simple choice," Nature Neuroscience, 13(10), 1292--1298. Krajbich, Ian and Rangel, Antonio (2011): "Multialternative drift-diffusion model predicts the relationship between visual fixations and choice in value-based decisions," Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(33), 13852--13857. Lévy-Garboua, Louis, Maafi, Hela, Masclet, David, and Terracol, Antoine (2012): "Risk aversion and framing effects," Experimental Economics, 15(1), 128--144. Loomes, Graham and Pogrebna, Ganna (2014): "Measuring individual risk attitudes when preferences are imprecise," Economic Journal, 124(576), 569--593. Loomes, Graham, Starmer, Chris, and Sugden, Robert (1989): "Preference reversal: information-processing effect or rational non-transitive choice?" Economic Journal, 99(395), 140--151. Loomes, Graham and Sugden, Robert (1995): "Incorporating a stochastic element into decision theories," European Economic Review, 39(3-4), 641--648. Loomis, John, Peterson, George, Champ, Patricia, Brown, Thomas, and Lucero, Beatrice (1998): "Paired comparison estimates of willingness to accept versus contingent valuation estimates of willingness to pay," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 35(4), 501--515. Lu, Jay (2016): "Random choice and private information," Econometrica, 84(6), 1983--2027. Luce, R. Duncan (1959a): Individual choice behavior: A theoretical analysis. Wiley: New York. Luce, R. Duncan (1959b): "On the possible psychophysical laws," Psychological Review, 66(2), 81--95. Luce, R. Duncan (1986): Response Times: Their Role in Inferring Elementary Mental Organization. New York: Oxford University Press. Luce, R. Duncan (1994): "Thurstone and Sensory Scaling: Then and Now," Psychological Review, 101(2), 271--277. Luce, R. Duncan (2005): "Measurement analogies: Comparisons of behavioral and physical measures," Psychometrika, 70(2), 227--251. Manzini, Paola, and Mariotti, Marco (2014): "Stochastic choice and consideration sets," Econometrica, 82(3), 1153--1176. Masatlioglu, Yusufcan, Nakajima, Daisuke, and Ozbay, Erkut Y. (2012): "Revealed Attention," American Economic Review, 102(5), 2183--2205. Mas-Colell, Andreu, Whinston, Michael D., and Green, Jerry R. (1995): Microeconomic Theory, New York: Oxford University Press. Matějka, Filip and McKay, Alisdair (2015): "Rational inattention to discrete choices: A new foundation for the multinomial logit model," American Economic Review, 105(1), 272--98. McFadden, Daniel (1974): "Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behavior," in Frontiers in Econometrics, Zarembka, Paul (Ed.), New York, Academic Press, 105--142. McFadden, Daniel (1976): "Quantal choice analaysis: A survey," Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, 5(4), 363--390. McFadden, Daniel (1981): "Econometric Models of Probabilistic Choice," in Structural Analysis of Discrete Data with Econometric Applications, Manski, Charles and McFadden, Daniel (Eds.), Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 198--272. McFadden, Daniel (2001): "Economic choices," American Economic Review, 91(3), 351--378. Moffatt, Peter G. (2005): "Stochastic choice and the allocation of cognitive effort," Experimental Economics, 8(4), 369--388. Mosteller, Frederick and Nogee, Philip (1951): "An experimental measurement of utility," Journal of Political Economy, 59(5), 371--404. Natenzon, Paulo (2019): "Random choice and learning," Journal of Political Economy, 127(1), 419--457. Navarro-Martinez, Daniel, Loomes, Graham, Isoni, Andrea, Butler, David, and Alaoui, Larbi (2018): "Boundedly rational expected utility theory," Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 57(3), 199--223. Olschewski, Sebastian, Newell, Ben, and Scheibehenne, Benjamin (2019): "How Basic Cognition Influences Experience-Based Economic Valuation," Working paper, University of Basel. Oud, Bastiaan, Krajbich, Ian, Miller, Kevin, Cheong, Jin Hyun, Botvinick, Matthew, and Fehr, Ernst (2016): "Irrational time allocation in decision-making," Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 283(1822), 20151439. Payne, John W., Bettman, James R., and Johnson, Eric J. (1993): The Adaptive Decision Maker. Cambridge University Press. Payne, John W., Braunstein, Myron L., and Carroll, John S. (1978): "Exploring predecisional behavior: An alternative approach to decision research," Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 22(1), 17--44. Polanía, Rafael, Krajbich, Ian, Grueschow, Marcus, and Ruff, Christian C. (2014): "Neural oscillations and synchronization differentially support evidence accumulation in perceptual and value-based decision making," Neuron, 82(3), 709--720. Psychology Software Tools, Inc. [E-Prime 2.0] (2012): Retrieved from http://www.pstnet.com. Ratcliff, Roger and McKoon, Gail (2008): "The Diffusion Decision Model: Theory and Data for Two-Choice Decision Tasks," Neural Computation, 20(4), 873--922. Reutskaja, Elena, Nagel, Rosemarie, Camerer, Colin F., and Rangel, Antonio (2011): "Search dynamics in consumer choice under time pressure: An eye-tracking study," American Economic Review, 101(2), 900--926. Rubinstein, Ariel (2013): "Response time and decision making: An experimental study," Judgment and Decision Making, 8(5), 540--551. Rubinstein, Ariel and Salant, Yuval (2006): "A model of choice from lists," Theoretical Economics, 1(1), 3--17. Sanjurjo, Adam (2015): "Search, memory, and choice error: an experiment," PloS ONE, 10(6), e0126508. Sanjurjo, Adam (2017): "Search with multiple attributes: Theory and empirics," Games and Economic Behavior, 104, 535--562. Schulz, Jonathan F., Fischbacher, Urs, Thöni, Christian, and Utikal, Verena (2014): "Affect and fairness: Dictator games under cognitive load," Journal of Economic Psychology, 41, 77--87. Sopher, Barry and Gigliotti, Gary (1993): "Intransitive cycles: Rational Choice or random error? An answer based on estimation of error rates with experimental data," Theory and Decision, 35(3), 311--336. Sopher, Barry and Narramore, J. Mattison (2000): "Stochastic choice and consistency in decision making under risk: An experimental study," Theory and Decision, 48(4), 323--350. Spiliopoulos, Leonidas and Ortmann, Andreas (2018): "The BCD of response time analysis in experimental economics," Experimental Economics, 21(2), 383--433. Stevens, S. S. (1961): "To honor Fechner and repeal his law," Science, 133(3446), 80--86. Swensson, Richard G. (1972): "The elusive tradeoff: Speed vs accuracy in visual discrimination tasks," Perception and Psychophysics, 12(1), 16--32. Teghtsoonian, Robert (1971): "On the exponents in Stevens' Law and the constant in Ekman's Law," Psychological Review, 78(1), 71--80. Thurstone, L. L. (1927a): "A law of comparative judgment," Psychological Review, 34(4), 273--286. Thurstone, L. L. (1927b): "Psychophysical Analysis," American Journal of Psychology, 38(3), 368--389. Tsetsos, Konstantinos, Moran, Rani, Moreland, James, Chater, Nick, Usher, Marius, and Summerfield, Christopher (2016): "Economic irrationality is optimal during noisy decision making," Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 113(11), 3102--3107. Tversky, Amos (1969): "Intransitivity of preferences," Psychological Review, 76(1), 31--48. Tyson, Christopher J. (2008): "Cognitive constraints, contraction consistency, and the satisficing criterion," Journal of Economic Theory, 138(1), 51--70. Volkmann, John (1934): "The relation of the time of judgment to the certainty of judgment," Psychological Bulletin, 31(9), 672--673. Webb, Ryan (2019): "The (neural) dynamics of stochastic choice," Management Science, 65(1), 230--255. Weber, Ernst (1834): De Tactu. (The Sense of Touch, translated 1978. Academic Press, New York.) Weibull, Jörgen W., Mattsson, Lars-Göran, and Voorneveld, Mark (2007): "Better may be worse: Some monotonicity results and paradoxes in discrete choice under uncertainty," Theory and Decision, 63(2), 121--151. Woodford, Michael (2014): "Stochastic choice: An optimizing neuroeconomic model," American Economic Review, 104(5), 495--500. Yellott, John I. (1977): "The relationship between Luce's Choice Axiom, Thurstone's Theory of Comparative Judgment, and the double exponential distribution," Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 15(2), 109--144. Zeigenfuse, Matthew D., Pleskac, Timothy J., and Liu, Taosheng (2014): "Rapid decisions from experience," Cognition, 131(2), 181--194. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/99417 |