Belbute, Jose and Caleiro, António (2010): Cross Country Evidence on Consumption Persistence.
This is the latest version of this item.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_22890.pdf Download (825kB) | Preview |
Abstract
The detection and measurement of the level of persistence on aggregate and disaggregate private consumption in Italy, Norway and United Kingdom are the main focus of the paper. Using a non-parametric methodology it is concluded that we cannot reject the presence of a significant degree of persistence in aggregate and disaggregate consumption in the three countries. These results are imperative from a policy point of view. Persistence in consumption does exist and cannot be ignored, whether the goal is to stabilize the level of output via consumption or to boost output via long-lasting increases in consumption. Given that cultural differences are not easily changed, a possible instrument is the interest rate.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Cross Country Evidence on Consumption Persistence |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Consumption, Persistence, Italy, Norway, United Kingdom. |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C1 - Econometric and Statistical Methods and Methodology: General > C14 - Semiparametric and Nonparametric Methods: General C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C2 - Single Equation Models ; Single Variables > C22 - Time-Series Models ; Dynamic Quantile Regressions ; Dynamic Treatment Effect Models ; Diffusion Processes E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy > E21 - Consumption ; Saving ; Wealth |
Item ID: | 22890 |
Depositing User: | José Belbute |
Date Deposited: | 28 May 2010 09:40 |
Last Modified: | 30 Sep 2019 16:42 |
References: | [1] Ascari, G., (2003);, “Price/Wage Staggering and Persistence: A Unifying Framework,” Journal of Economic Surveys, 17, 511-540. [2] Belbute, J., P. Brito, (2008); “On Sustainable Endogenous Growth Under Intertemporally Dependent Preferences,” ICFAI Journal of Environmental Economics, 6(4), 7-28. [3] Belbute, José, & António Caleiro (2009); “Measuring the Persistence on Consumption in Portugal,” Journal of Applied Economic Sciences, IV, 2(8), Summer, 185-202. [4] Bouakez, H., Kano, T., (2006); “Learning-By-Doing or Habit Formation?,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 9, 508-524. [5] Caleiro, António (2009); “How Upside Down Are Political Business Cycles When There is Output Persistence,” Research in Economics, 63, 1, 22-26. [6] Carroll, C. (2000); Saving and Growth with Habit Formation. American Economic Review , 90 (3), pp. 341-355. [7] Carrol, C., J. Overland, and D. Weil (1997); Comparison Utility in a Growth Model, Journal of Economic Growth 2 (4), 339-397. [8] Chow, G. (1960); Tests of Equality Between Sets of Coefficients in Two Linear Regressions. Econometrica , 28, pp. 591-605. [9] Clemente, J, A. Montanés and M. Reyes (1998); “Testing for a Unit Root in Variables With a Double Change in the Mean,” Economic Letters, 59, 175-182. [10] Cogley, T., Nason, J., (1995); “Output Dynamics in Real-Business-Cycle Models,” American Economic Review, 85, 492-511. [11] Constantinides, G. (1990); “Habit Formation: a Resolution of the Equity Premium Puzzle,” Journal of Political Economy , 98, 519-543. [12] Dias, Daniel, & C. R. Marques (2010); “Using Mean Reversion as a Measure of Persistence,” Economic Modelling, 27, 262-273. [13] Dickey, D. and W. Fuller (1979); “Distribution of Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series With a Unit Root,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74,427-431. [14] Dusenberry. (1949);“Income-Consumption Relations and their Implications,” in Metzler, Income, Employment and Public Policy. Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavio. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [15] Elliott , G. T. Rotemberg and J. Stock (1996);”Efficient Tests for an Autoregressive Unit Root,” Econometrica, 64, 813-836. [16] Gärtner, M., (1996); “Political Business Cycles When Real Activity is Persistent,” Journal of Macroeconomics, 18, 679-692. [17] Gärtner, M., (1999); “The Election Cycle in the Inflation Bias: Evidence From the G-7 Countries,” European Journal of Political Economy, 15, 705-725. [18] Giugale, M., Korobow, A., (2000); “Shock Persistence and the Choice of Foreign Exchange Regime: An Empirical Note from Mexico,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2371. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=630755. [19] Guender, A., (2006); “Stabilising Properties of Discretionary Monetary Policies in a Small Open Economy,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 116, pp. 309 - 326. [20] Hodrick, R. and Prescott, E.(1981); “Post-war U.S. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation,” Working Paper, Carnegie-Mellon, University. Reprinted in Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 29, No. 1, February 1997. [21] Jonsson, G., (1997); “Monetary Politics and Unemployment Persistence,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 39, 303-325. [22] Kiley, M., (2000); “Endogenous Price Stickiness and Business Cycle Persistence,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 32, 28-53. [23] Lahiri, A., and M. Puhakka (1998); “Habit Persistence in Overlapping Generations Economies Under Pure Exchange” Journal of Economic Theory 78, 176-186. [24] Lockwood, B., (1997); “State-Contingent Inflation Contracts and Unemployment Persistence,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29, 286-299. [25] Marques, Carlos Robalo (2004); “Inflation Persistence: Facts or Artefacts?,” Working Paper 8, Banco de Portugal, June. [26] Maury, T.-P., Tripier, F., (2003); “Output Persistence in Human Capital-Based Growth Models,” Economics Bulletin, 5, 1-8. [27] Perron, P. and T. Vagelsang (1992); “Nonsatationarity and Level Shifts With an Application to Purchasing Power Parity,” Journal of Business & Economic Statistic, Vol 10, 3, 301-320. [28] Perron, P. (1989); “The Great Crash, the Oil Price Shock and the Unit Root Hypothesis,” Econometrica, 57, 1361-1401. [29] Rotemberg, J., Woodford, M., (1997); “An Optimization Based Econometric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy,” In: Rotemberg, J., Bernanke, B., (Eds.). NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997. Cambridge (MA): The MIT Press, 297-346. [30] Ryder, H. E. and G. M. Heal (1973); “Optimum Growth With Intertemporally Dependent ,” Preferences. Review of Economic Studies 40, 1–33. [31] Shieh, J-Y. (2000); “Addictive Behavior and Endogenous Growth,” Journal of Economics, Vol. 72, 3, pp 263-273. [32] Svensson, L., (1997); “Optimal Inflation Targets, “Conservative,” Central Banks, and Linear Inflation Contracts,” American Economic Review, 87, 98-114. [33] Taylor, J., (1980); “Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts,” Journal of Political Economy, 88, 1-23. [34] Wang, P.-f., Wen, Y., (2006); “Another Look at Sticky Prices and Output Persistence,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 30, 2533-2552. [35] Wendner, R. (2002); “Capital Accumulation and Habit Formation,” Economics Bulletin 4, 1-10. [36] Wendner, R. (2000); “A Policy Lesson From an Overlapping Generations Model of Habit Persistence,” Working paper, Department of Economics, University of California (Berkeley). |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/22890 |
Available Versions of this Item
-
Cross Country Evidence on Consumption Persistence. (deposited 09 Apr 2010 20:18)
- Cross Country Evidence on Consumption Persistence. (deposited 28 May 2010 09:40) [Currently Displayed]