Sanderson, Rohnn (2013): Does Monetary Policy cause Randomness or Chaos? A Case Study from the European Central Bank. Published in: Banks and Bank Systems No. 4 (18 December 2013): pp. 55-61.
Preview |
PDF
BBS_en_2013_04_Sanderson.pdf Download (166kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Using the HICP (Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices) the author tests the series for the makeup of its dynamic components both before and after the start of stage three of the European Central Bank’s (ECB) monetary policy directive. While it appears ECB is meeting its stated objective, it is perhaps more important to address the composition of the lag and volatility of monetary policy to see how a policy change alters the fundamental dynamic structure of an economic system. The HICP data provides a good natural experiment for assessing structural change. This is important because while a policy may achieve its goal(s), in doing so it may alter the fundamental nature of how that system behaves, potentially causing the system to be more volatile or more sensitive to exogenous shocks in the future. Changes to the fundamental nature of a dynamic system can mean that future policies, that are similar to the present policies, could have very different impacts on that very same system in terms of both long run and short run effects. The paper finds that while the ECB may be meeting its stated objectives, it may be potentially increasing the degree and severity of future short run deflationary/inflationary cycles from similar policies in the future due to the type of random and deterministic components in the system. More data and further study is needed to determine the long-term affects of monetary policy in economic systems as many economic cycles are indeed very long.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Does Monetary Policy cause Randomness or Chaos? A Case Study from the European Central Bank |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | dynamic systems, Hurst exponent, chaos, long-term memory, monetary policy |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C5 - Econometric Modeling > C50 - General E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E4 - Money and Interest Rates > E40 - General G - Financial Economics > G1 - General Financial Markets > G18 - Government Policy and Regulation |
Item ID: | 52537 |
Depositing User: | Dr. Rohnn Sanderson |
Date Deposited: | 08 Jan 2014 06:52 |
Last Modified: | 30 Sep 2019 20:55 |
References: | Arthur, W. Brian (2013). “Complexity Economics: A Different Framework for Economic Thought”, SFI, Working Paper, Santa Fe Institute, Web. 10 Sept. Baumol, William J. and Jess Benhabib (1989). “Chaos: significance, mechanism, and economic applications”, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, pp. 77-105.Banks and Bank Systems, Volume 8, Issue 4, 2013 “ECB: Objective of monetary policy” (2013). ECB: European Central Bank home page, July 16, <http://www.ecb.europa.eu/mopo/intro/objective/html/index.en.html>. Elert, Glenn (2013). “3.3 Fractal Dimension” hypertextbook.com. Chaos Hypertextbook, n.d. Web. 11 Sept. <http://hypertextbook.com/chaos/33.shtml>. “Euro area (changing composition) (2013). HICP − Overall index, Annual rate of change, Eurostat, Neither seasonally nor working day adjusted − Quick View − ECB Statistical Data Warehouse”. ECB Statistical Data Warehouse. N. p., n.d. Web. 16 July <http://sdw.ecb.europa.eu/quickview.do?SERIES_KEY=122.ICP.M U2.N.000000.4ANR>. European Central Bank (2013). Statutes of the ECB, August 22, <www.ecb.europa.eu/ecb/legal/ pdf/en_statute_from_c_11520080509en02010328.pdf>. Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French (1988). “Permanent and temporary components of stock prices”, Journal of Political Economy, 96, pp. 246-273. Friedman, Milton (1961). “The Lag In Effect Of Monetary Policy”, Journal of Political Economy 69 (5), pp. 447. HICP Definition (2013). HICP Definition. ECB, n.d. Web. 12 Sept. <https://www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/prices/ hicp/html/index.en.html>. Howitt, Peter, and Robert Clower (2000). “The Emergence of Economic Organization”, Journal of Economic Be- havior and Organization, 41, pp. 55-84. Hsieh, David A. (1991). “Chaos and nonlinear dynamics: application to financial markets”, The Journal of Finance 46 (5), pp. 1839-1877. Hurst, Harold (1951). “Long-term storage capacity of reservoirs”. Transactions of the American Society of Civil Engineers, 116, pp. 770-799. Lo, Andrew W. (1991). “Long-term memory in stock market prices”, Econometrica, 59 (5), pp. 1279-1313. Sanderson, Rohnn (2013). “An Application of Dynamic Economic Systems to the Gold Market”, University of New Mexico, Septenber 11 <repository.unm.edu/bitstream/handle/1928/10296/sandersondissertationfinalwithsig. pdf?sequence=1>. Sanderson, Rohnn (2011). “Compartmentalizing Gold Prices”, International Journal of Economic Sciences and Applied Research, IJESAR. Web. 10 Sept., pp. 99-124. Sanderson, Rohnn (2013). “A Short Primer in Dynamic Systems” Rohnn Sanderson, Sept 11 available at <www.businessquickstat.com/files/ashortprimerindynsystemsupdate 2012. PDF>. Taleb, Nassim (2007). The black swan: the impact of the highly improbable, New York, Random House. Tamari, Ben (2012). Conservation and Symmetry Laws and Stabilization Programs in Economics, 2012 ed, Isreal. Wolf, A., J. Swift, H. Swinney, and J. Vastano (1985). “Determining Lyapunov Exponents from a Time Series”. Physica D: Nonlinear Phenomena, 16 (3), pp. 285-317. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/52537 |