Kim, Chulyoung (2016): Adversarial Bias, Litigation, and the Daubert Test: An Economic Approach.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_69978.pdf Download (345kB) | Preview |
Abstract
The last few decades have seen a dramatic shift in the admissibility of expert testimony in American courtrooms from a laissez-faire approach to a strict standard for admissibility, often called the Daubert test. The implicit rationale behind such a stringent standard for admissibility is the trier of fact's vulnerability to adversarial bias, which many legal scholars and practitioners assume to be rampant. Employing a standard litigation model in the literature, I demonstrate that client-expert relationships may not always exhibit adversarial bias and that a litigant may voluntarily present neutral expert testimony under certain situations. I also show that a litigant is more likely to deploy hired guns if the litigation environment is more favorable to his cause. In particular, the burden of proof assignment and the court's prior belief are shown to influence adversarial bias.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Adversarial Bias, Litigation, and the Daubert Test: An Economic Approach |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | litigation game; evidence distortion; adversarial bias; Daubert test |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory > C72 - Noncooperative Games D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty > D82 - Asymmetric and Private Information ; Mechanism Design K - Law and Economics > K4 - Legal Procedure, the Legal System, and Illegal Behavior > K41 - Litigation Process |
Item ID: | 69978 |
Depositing User: | Chulyoung Kim |
Date Deposited: | 11 Mar 2016 21:05 |
Last Modified: | 28 Sep 2019 20:17 |
References: | Adrogue, S. and A. Ratliff (2003): “The Independent Expert Evolution: From the “Path of Least Resistance” to the “Road less Traveled?”,” Texas Tech Law Review, 34, 843–897. Angell, M. (1997): Science on Trial: The Clash of Medical Evidence and the Law in the Breast Implant Case, W. W. Norton & Company. Bernstein, D. E. (2008): “Expert Witnesses, Adversarial Bias, and the (Partial) Failure of the Daubert Revolution,” Iowa Law Review, 93, 451–489. Bernstein, D. E. (2013): “The Misbegotten Judicial Resistance to the Daubert Revolution,” Notre Dame Law Review, 89, 27–70. Boudreau, C. and M. D. McCubbins (2008): “Nothing But the Truth? Experiments on Adversarial Competition, Expert Testimony, and Decision Making,” Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, 5, 751–789. Cecil, J. S. and T. E. Willging (1994): “Accepting Daubert’s Invitation: Defining a Role for Court-Appointed Experts in Assessing Scientific Validity,” Emory Law Journal, 43, 995–1070. Cooper, J. C. (2015): “Timing and Disposition of Daubert Motions in Federal District Courts: An Empirical Examination,” Working Paper. Daughety, A. F. and J. F. Reinganum (2000a): “Appealing judgments,” RAND Journal of Economics, 31, 502–525. Daughety, A. F. and J. F. Reinganum (2000b): “On the economics of trials: adversarial process, evidence, and equilibrium bias,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 16, 365–394. Demougin, D. and C. Fluet (2005): “Deterrence versus Judicial Error: A Comparative View of Standards of Proof,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 161, 193– 206. Demougin, D. and C. Fluet (2006): “Preponderance of Evidence,” European Economic Review, 50, 963–976. Demougin, D. and C. Fluet (2008): “Rules of Proof, Courts, and Incentives,” RAND Journal of Economics, 39, 20–40. Dixon, L. and B. Gill (2001): “Changes in the Standards for Admitting Expert Evidence in Federal Civil Cases Since the Daubert Decision,” RAND Institute for Civil Justice. Emons, W. and C. Fluet (2009a): “Accuracy Versus Falsification Costs: The Optimal Amount of Evidence under Different Procedures,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 25, 134–156. Emons, W. and C. Fluet (2009b): “Adversarial versus Inquisitorial Testimony,” Working Paper. Froeb, L. and B. Kobayashi (1996): “Naive, Biased, Yet Bayesian: Can Juries Interpret Selectively Produced Evidence?” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 12, 257– 276. Green, M. D. (1998): Bendectin and Birth Defects: The Challenges of Mass Toxic Substances Litigation, University of Pennsylvania Press. Groscup, J. L., S. D. Penrod, C. A. Studebaker, M. T. Huss, and K. M. O’Neil (2002): “The Effects of Daubert on the Admissibility of Expert Testimony in State and Federal Criminal Cases,” Psychology, Public Policy, and Law, 8, 339–372. Gross, S. R. (1991): “Expert Evidence,” Wisconsin Law Review, 1113–1232. Guinther, J. (1988): The Jury in America, New York: Facts on File Publications. Hand, L. (1901): “Historical and Practical Considerations regarding Expert Testimony,” Harvard Law Review, 15, 40–58. Haw, R. (2012): “Adversarial Economics in Antitrust Litigation: Losing Academic Consensus in the Battle of the Experts,” Northwestern University Law Review, 106, 1261–1305. Hillman, T. (2002): “Using Court-Appointed Experts,” New England Law Review, 36, 587– 591. Kalven, H. and H. Zeisel (1966): The American Jury, New York: Little, Brown. Kaplan, L. A. (2006): “2005 Milton Handler Antitrust Review: Experts in the Courthouse: Problems and Opportunities,” Columbia Business Law Review, 2006, 247–260. Kaye, D. H., D. E. Bernstein, and J. L. Mnookin (2010): The New Wigmore: A Treatise on Evidence - Expert Evidence, Aspen Publishers, 2nd ed. Kim, C. (2014): “Adversarial and Inquisitorial Procedures with Information Acquisition,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 30, 767–803. Kim, C. (2015a): “Centralized vs. Decentralized Institutions for Expert Testimony,” Working Paper. Kim, C. (2015b): “An Economic Rationale for Dismissing Low-Quality Experts in Trial,” Working Paper. Kim, C. and P. S. Koh (2015): “Court-Appointed Expert and Accuracy in Adversarial Litigation,” Working Paper. Krafka, C., M. A. Dunn, M. T. Johnson, J. S. Cecil, and D. Miletich (2002): “Judge and Attorney Experiences, Practices, and Concerns Regarding Expert Testimony in Federal Civil Trials,” Psychology, Public Policy, and Law, 8, 309–332. Langbein, J. H. (1985): “The German Advantage in Civil Procedure,” University of Chicago Law Review, 52, 823–866. Liptak, A. (2008): “One Footnote, a Debate Over the Tangles of Law, Science and Money,” online at www.nytimes.com. Milgrom, P. and J. Roberts (1986): “Relying on the Information of Interested Parties,” RAND Journal of Economics, 17, 18–32. Milgrom, P. R. (1981): “Good News and Bad News: Representation Theorems and Applications,” Bell Journal of Economics, 12, 380–391. Mnookin, J. L. (2008): “Expert Evidence, Partisanship, and Epistemic Competence,” Brooklyn Law Review, 73, 587–611. Robertson, C. T. (2010): “Blind Expertise,” New York University Law Review, 85, 174–257. Runkle, D. (2001): “Court Appointed Scientific Experts: A Demonstration Project of the American Association for the Advancement of Science,” Risk Decision and Policy, 6, 139– 143. Sanchirico, C. W. (2001): “Character Evidence and the Object of Trial,” Columbia Law Review, 101, 1227–1311. Sanders, J. (1998): Bendectin on Trial: A Study of Mass Tort Litigation, University of Michigan Press. Schrag, J. and S. Scotchmer (1994): “Crime and prejudice: The use of character evidence in criminal trials,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 10, 319–342. Schuck, P. H. (1988): Agent Orange on Trial: Mass Toxic Disasters in the Courts, Belknap Press. Shin, H. (1998): “Adversarial and Inquisitorial Procedures in Arbitration,” RAND Journal of Economics, 29, 378–405. Sidak, J. G. (2013): “Court-Appointed Neutral Economic Experts,” Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 9, 359–394. Simon, R. J. (1975): The Jury System in America: A Critical Overview, California: Sage Publications. Sorrel, A. L. (2007): “In Search of Truthful Testimony: Scrutinizing Expert Witnesses,” online at www.amednews.com. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/69978 |