Rodriguez-Lara, Ismael and Ponti, Giovanni (2017): Social Motives vs Social Influence: an Experiment on Time Preferences.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_76486.pdf Download (4MB) | Preview |
Abstract
We report experimental evidence on the effects of social preferences on intertemporal decisions. To this aim, we design an intertemporal Dictator Game to test whether Dictators modify their discounting behavior when their own decision is imposed on their matched Recipients. We run four different treatments to identify the effect of payoffs externalities from those related to information and beliefs. Our descriptive statistics show that heterogeneous social time preferences and information about others’ time preferences are significant determinants of choices: Dictators display a marked propensity to account for the intertemporal preferences of Recipients, both in the presence of externalities (social motives) and/or when they know about the decisions of their matched partners (social influence). We also perform a structural estimation exercise to control for heterogeneity in risk attitudes. As for individual behavior, our estimates confirm previous studies in that high risk aversion is associated with low discounting. As for social behavior, we find that social motives outweigh social influence, especially when we restrict our sample to pairs of Dictators and Recipients who satisfy minimal consistency conditions.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Social Motives vs Social Influence: an Experiment on Time Preferences |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | intertemporal choices, time preferences, risk and social preferences, social influence, beliefs (JEL: C91, D70, D81) |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C9 - Design of Experiments D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D70 - General D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty > D81 - Criteria for Decision-Making under Risk and Uncertainty |
Item ID: | 76486 |
Depositing User: | Dr Ismael Rodriguez-lara |
Date Deposited: | 01 Feb 2017 10:00 |
Last Modified: | 28 Sep 2019 07:55 |
References: | [1] Abdellaoui M, L’Haridon O, Paraschiv C (2013). Do Couples Discount Future Consequences Less than Individuals?, University of Rennes, WP 2013-20. [2] Ai AC, Norton EC (2003). “Interaction terms in logit and probit models”, Economics Letters, 80(1), 123-129. [3] Andersen S, Fountain J, Harrison GW, Rutstrom EE (2014). “Estimating subjective probabilities”, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 48(3), 207-229. [4] Andersen S, Harrison GW, Lau M, Rutstrom EE (2006). “Elicitation using multiple price lists”, Experimental Economics, 9(4), 383-405. [5] Andersen S, Harrison GW, Lau M, Rutstrom EE (2008). “Eliciting Risk and Time Preferences”, Econometrica ,76(3), 583-618. [6] Andersen S, Harrison GW, Lau M, Rutstrom EE (2014). “Discounting Behavior: A Reconsideration”, European Economic Review, 71, 15-33. [7] Anderson JC, Burks SV, DeYoung CV, Rustichini A (2011). Toward the Integration of Personality Theory and Decision Theory in the Explanation of Economic Behavior, IZA Discussion Paper No.6750. [8] Andersson O, Holm HJ, Tyran JR, Wengstrom E. (2016) “Deciding for Others Reduces Loss Aversion”, Management Science, 62(1), 29-36. [9] Andreoni J, Kuhn MA, Sprenger C (2015). “Measuring Time Preferences: A Comparison of Experi- mental Methods”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 116, 451-464. [10] Andreoni J, Sprenger C (2012a). “Estimating Time Preferences from Convex Budgets”, American Economic Review, 102(7), 3333-3356. [11] Andreoni, J, Sprenger C (2012b). “Risk Preferences Are Not Time Preferences”, American Economic Review, 102(7), 3357-3376. [12] Asch, SE (1955). “Opinions and social pressure”, Readings about the Social Animal, 193, 17-26. [13] Banerjee, AV (1992). “A simple model of herd behavior ”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(3), 797-817. [14] Benhabib J, Bisin A, Schotter A (2010). “Present-bias, quasi-hyperbolic discounting, and fixed costs”, Games and Economic Behavior, 69(2), 205-223. [15] Benjamin DJ, Brown SA, Shapiro JM (2013). “Who is ‘behavioral’? Cognitive ability and anomalous preferences”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(6), 1231-1255. [16] Bikhchandani S, Hirshleifer D, Welch I (1992). “A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades”, Journal of Political Economy, 100(5), 992-1026. [17] Browning M (2000). “The Saving Behavior of a Two-Person Household”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 102(2), 235-251. [18] Burks SV, Carpenter JP, Goette I, Rustichini A (2009). “Cognitive skills affect economic preferences, strategic behavior, and job attachment”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106, 7745- 7750. [19] Burton RF, Bhagavanlal I, Shivaram B (2009). The Kama Sutra of Vatsyayana, Norilana Books. [20] Cabrales A, Miniaci R, Piovesan M, Ponti G (2008). “Social Preferences and Strategic Uncertainty: an Experiment on Markets and Contracts”, American Economic Review, 100(5), 2261-2278. [21] Chakravarty S, Harrison GW, Haruvy EE, Rutstr ̈om EE (2011). “Are You Risk Averse over Other People’s Money?”, Southern Economic Review, 77(4), 901-913. [22] Cheung SL (2015). “Comment on Risk preferences are not time preferences: On the elicitation of time preference under conditions of risk”, American Economic Review, 105 (7), 2242-2260. [23] Coller M, Williams MB (1999). “Eliciting Individual Discount Rates”, Experimental Economics, 2, 107-127. [24] Coller M, Harrison GW, Rutstrom EE (2012). “Latent Process Heterogeneity in Discounting Behavior”, Oxford Economic Papers, 64(2), 375-391. [25] Cubitt R, Starmer C, Sugden R (1998). “On the validity of the random lottery incentive system”, Experimental Economics, 1(2), 115-131. [26] Cueva C, Iturbe-Ormaetxe I, Mata-Perez E, Ponti G, Sartarelli M, Yu H, Zhukova V (2016). “Cognitive (Ir)Reflection and Behavioral Data: New Experimental Evidence”, Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 64, 81-93. [27] Dean M, Ortoleva P (2012). Is it All Connected? A Testing Ground for Unified Theories of Behavioral Economics Phenomena, Columbia University, mimeo. [28] Eckel CC, Grossman PJ (2008). “Forecasting risk attitudes: An experimental study using actual and forecast gamble choices”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 68, 1-7. [29] Epper T, Fehr-Duda H, Bruhin A (2011). “Viewing the future through a warped lens: Why uncertainty generates hyperbolic discounting”, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 43(3), 169-203. [30] Fehr E, Schmidt KM (1999). “A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817-868. [31] Feri F, Mel ́endez-Jim ́enez, MA, Ponti G, Vega-Redondo, F (2011). “Error cascades in observational learning: An experiment on the chinos game”, Games and Economic Behavior, 73(1), 136-146. [32] Fischbacher U (2007). “z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments”, Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171-178. [33] Frederick S (2005). “Cognitive reflection and decision making”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19, 24-42. [34] Frederick S, Loewenstein G, O’Donoghue T (2002). “Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review”, Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 351-401. [35] Frignani N, Ponti G (2012). “Social vs. Risk Preferences under the Veil of Ignorance”, Economics Letters, 116, 143-146. [36] Glaeser E, Laibson D, Scheinkman J, Soutter C (2000). “Measuring trust”, Quarterly Journal of Eco- nomics, 115, 811-846. [37] Goeree JK, Yariv L (2015). “Conformity in the Lab”, Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1-14. [38] Halevy Y (2008). “Strotz Meets Allais: Diminishing Impatience and the Certainty Effect”, American Economic Review, 98 (3), 1145-1162. [39] Harrison GW, Lau M, Rutstrom EE (2013). “Identifying Time Preferences with Experiments: Comment.”, Center for the Economic Analysis of Risk Working Paper WP-2013-09. [40] Harrison GW, Lau M, Rutstr ̈om EE, Sullivan MB (2005). “Eliciting Risk and Time Preferences Using Field Experiments: Some Methodological Issues”, in J. Carpenter, G.W. Harrison and J.A. List (eds.), Field Experiments in Economics, Greenwich, CT, JAI Press, Research in Experimental Economics, Volume 10, Emerald Group Publiushing Limited, 41-196. [41] Harrison GW, Lau M, Rutstr ̈om EE, Tarazona-Gomes M (2013). “Preferences over social risk”, Oxford Economic Papers, 65, 25-46. [42] Harrison GW, Miniaci R, Ponti G. Social Preferences over Utilities, LUISS Guido Carli, mimeo. [43] Harrison GW, Rutstr ̈om EE (2008). “Risk Aversion in the Laboratory”, in Cox JC, Harrison GW (eds.), Risk Aversion in Experiments (Research in Experimental Economics, Volume 12), Emerald Group Publishing Limited, 41-196. [44] Hey JD, Lee J (2005). “Do Subjects Separate (or Are They Sophisticated)?”, Experimental Economics, 8, 233-265. [45] Hey JD, Orme C (1994). “Investigating Generalizations of Expected Utility Theory Using Experimental Data”, Econometrica, 62(6),1291-1326. [46] Holt CA, Laury SK (2002). “Risk Aversion and Incentive Effects”, American Economic Review, 92(3), 1644-1655. [47] Holt CA, Laury SK (2005). “Risk Aversion and Incentive Effects: New Data without Order Effects”, American Economic Review, 95(3), 902-904. [48] Hung AA, Plott CR (2001). “Information cascades: Replication and an extension to majority rule and conformity-rewarding institutions”, American Economic Review, 91(5), 1508-1520. [49] Karaca-Mandic P, Norton EC, Dowd B (2012). “Interaction terms in nonlinear models”, Health services research, 47(1), 255-274. [50] Kovarik J (2009). “Giving it now or later: Altruism and discounting”, Economics Letters, 102(3), 152- 154. [51] Krupka E, Weber R (2009). “The focusing and informational effects of norms on pro-social behaviour”, Journal of Economic Psychology, 30, 307-320. [52] Laury SK, McInnes MM, Swarthout JT (2012). “Avoiding the curves: Direct elicitation of time prefer- ences”, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 44, 181-217. [53] Lazaro A, Barberan R, Rubio, E (2001). “Private and social time preferences for health and money: An empirical estimation”, Health Economics, 10(4), 351-356. [54] Lazaro A, Barberan R, Rubio, E (2002). “The discounted utility model and social preferences: Some alternative formulations to conventional discounting”, Journal of Economic Psychology, 23(3), 317-337. [55] Mahboub-Ahari A, Pourreza A, Akbari Sari A, Rahimi Foroushani A, Heydari, H (2014). “Stated Time Preferences for Health: A Systematic Review and Meta Analysis of Private and Social Discount Rates. Journal of Research in Health Sciences, 14(3), 181-186. [56] Mazzocco M (2004). “Saving, Risk Sharing, and Preferences for Risk”, American Economic Review, 94(4), 1169-1182. [57] Mazzocco M (2007). “Household Intertemporal Behaviour: A Collective Characterization and a Test of Commitment”, Review of Economic Studies, 74(3), 857-895. [58] Meier S, Sprenger CD (2015). “Temporal stability of time preferences”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 97(2), 273-286. [59] Miao B, Zhong S (2015). “Comment on ‘Risk Preferences Are Not Time Preferences’: Separating Risk and Time Preference”, American Economic Review, 105(7), 2272-2286. [60] Moreno B, Ramos-Sosa MP (2016). “Conformity in voting”, Social Choice and Welfare, forthcoming. [61] Phelphs ES, Pollak RA (1968). “On Second-Best National Saving and Game-Equilibrium Growth”, Review of Economic Studies, 35(2), 185-199. [62] Ponti G, Rodriguez-Lara I (2015). “Social Preferences and Cognitive Reflection: Evidence from a Dictator Game Experiment”, Frontiers in Behavioral Neuroscience, 9:146. [63] Robberstad, B. (2005). “Estimation of private and social time preferences for health in northern Tanzania”, Social Science and Medicine, 61(7), 1597-1607. [64] Rodriguez-Lara, I. (2010). “Doing it on time under the influence of others”, in Essays on Behavioral and Experimental Economics, unpublished dissertation, Universidad de Alicante. [65] Sherif, M (1937). “An experimental approach to the study of attitudes”, Sociometry, 1, 90-98. [66] Starmer C, Sugden R (1991). “Does the Random-Lottery Incentive System Elicit True Preferences? An Experimental Investigation”, American Economic Review, 81(4), 971-978. [67] Sutter M, Kocher MG, Gl ̈atzle-Ru ̈etzler D, Trautmann ST (2013). “Impatience and Uncertainty: Exper- imental Decisions Predict Adolescents’ Field Behavior”, American Economic Review, 103(1), 510-531. [68] Tanaka T, Camerer CC, Nguyen Q (2010). “Risk and Time Preferences: Linking Experimental and Household Survey Data from Vietnam”, American Economic Review, 100(1), 557-571. [69] Winter E (2004). “Incentives and Discrimination”, American Economic Review, 94(3), 764-773. [70] Winter E, Lopez-Pintado D, Ponti G (2008). ”Inequality or Strategic Uncertainty? An Experimental Study on Incentives and Hierarchy”, in Innocenti A, Sbriglia P (eds.), Games Rationality & Behaviour, Palgrave Macmillan, 235-255. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/76486 |