De Dominicis, Piero (2020): Routinization and Covid-19: a comparison between United States and Portugal.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_101003.pdf Download (1MB) | Preview |
Abstract
The purpose of this paper is to identify what is the role of automatization in increasing wage inequality, making a comparison between the two countries. Using PSID and Quadros de Pessoal, we find that labor income dynamics are strongly determined by the variance of the individual fixed component. This effect is drastically reduced by adding information on workers' occupational tasks, confirming that decreasing price of capital and the consequent replacement of routine manual workers have deepened wage inequality. During the current crisis, we find that the ability to keep working is strongly related with the occupation type. As such, we simulate the impact of a permanent demand shock using an overlapping-generations model with incomplete markets and heterogeneous agents to quantitatively predict the impact of Covid-19 and lockdown measures on wage premium and earnings inequality. We find that wage premia and earnings dispersion increase, suggesting that earnings inequality will increase at the expenses of manual workers.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Routinization and Covid-19: a comparison between United States and Portugal |
English Title: | Routinization and Covid-19: a comparison between United States and Portugal |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Routinization, Wage Inequality, Covid-19, Income processes, Teleworking |
Subjects: | E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy > E21 - Consumption ; Saving ; Wealth J - Labor and Demographic Economics > J2 - Demand and Supply of Labor > J23 - Labor Demand J - Labor and Demographic Economics > J3 - Wages, Compensation, and Labor Costs > J31 - Wage Level and Structure ; Wage Differentials |
Item ID: | 101003 |
Depositing User: | Mr Piero De Dominicis |
Date Deposited: | 19 Jun 2020 02:50 |
Last Modified: | 19 Jun 2020 02:50 |
References: | [1] Acemoglu, Daron, & Restrepo, Pascual. 2018. The race between man and machine: Implications of technology for growth, factor shares, and employment. American Economic Review, 108(6), 1488–1542. [2] Acemoglu, Daron, & Restrepo, Pascual. 2020. Robots and jobs: Evidence from US labor markets. Journal of Political Economy, 128(6), 2188–2244. [3] Autor, David H, Levy, Frank, & Murnane, Richard J. 2003. The skill content of recent technological change: An empirical exploration. The Quarterly journal of economics, 118(4), 1279–1333. [4] Autor, David H, Katz, Lawrence F, & Kearney, Melissa S. 2006. The polarization of the US labor market. The American economic review, 96(2), 189–194. [5] Baumeister, Christiane, & Hamilton, James D. 2015. Sign restrictions, structural vector autoregressions, and useful prior information. Econometrica, 83(5), 1963–1999. [6] Benabou, Roland, & Tirole, Jean. 2002. Self-confidence and personal motivation. The quarterly journal of economics, 117(3), 871–915. [7] Brinca, Pedro, Holter, Hans A, Krusell, Per, & Malafry, Laurence. 2016. Fiscal multipliers in the 21st century. Journal of Monetary Economics, 77, 53–69. [8] Brinca, Pedro, Homem Ferreira, Miguel, Franco, Francesco A, Holter, Hans Aasnes, & Malafry, Laurence. 2019a. Fiscal consolidation programs and income inequality. Available at SSRN 3071357. [9] Brinca, Pedro, Duarte, Joao B, Holter, Hans A, Oliveira, Jo˜ao G, et al. 2019b. Investment-Specific Technological Change, Taxation and Inequality in the US. Tech. rept. University Library of Munich, Germany. [10] Brinca, Pedro, Faria-e Castro, Miguel, Homem Ferreira, Miguel, & Holter, Hans. 2019c. The nonlinear effects of fiscal policy. FRB St. Louis Working Paper. [11] Brinca, Pedro, Duarte, Joao B., & e Castro, Miguel Faria. 2020. Measuring Sectoral Supply and Demand Shocks during COVID-19. Tech. rept. Federal Reserve of St.Louis. [12] Chakraborty, Indraneel, Holter, Hans A, & Stepanchuk, Serhiy. 2015. Marriage stability, taxation and aggregate labor supply in the US vs. Europe. Journal of Monetary Economics, 72, 1–20. [13] Coelho, Jose. 2020. Universal basic income and skill-biased technological change. [14] Cortes, Guido Matias, Jaimovich, Nir, Nekarda, Christopher J, & Siu, Henry E. 2014. The micro and macro of disappearing routine jobs: A flows approach. Tech. rept. National Bureau of Economic Research. [15] Dingel, Jonathan I, & Neiman, Brent. 2020. How many jobs can be done at home? Tech. rept. National Bureau of Economic Research. [16] Eden, Maya, & Gaggl, Paul. 2015. On the welfare implications of automation. The World Bank. [17] Ferreira, Ana. 2019. Skill-biased technological change and inequality in the US. [18] Ferriere, Axelle, & Navarro, Gaston. 2014. The heterogeneous effects of government spending: It’s all about taxes. [19] Fonseca, Tiago, Lima, Francisco, & Pereira, Sonia C. 2018. Job polarization, technological change and routinization: Evidence for Portugal. Labour Economics, 51, 317–339. [20] Goos, Maarten, & Manning, Alan. 2007. Lousy and lovely jobs: The rising polarization of work in Britain. The review of economics and statistics, 89(1), 118–133. [21] Goos, Maarten, Manning, Alan, & Salomons, Anna. 2009. Job polarization in Europe. American economic review, 99(2), 58–63. [22] Guerreiro, Joao, Rebelo, Sergio, & Teles, Pedro. 2017. Should robots be taxed? Tech. rept. National Bureau of Economic Research. [23] Heathcote, Jonathan, Perri, Fabrizio, & Violante, Giovanni L. 2010. Unequal we stand: An empirical analysis of economic inequality in the United States, 1967–2006. Review of Economic dynamics, 13(1), 15–51. [24] Heathcote, Jonathan, Storesletten, Kjetil, & Violante, Giovanni L. 2017. Optimal tax progressivity: An analytical framework. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132(4), 1693–1754. [25] Heathcote, Jonathan, Storesletten, Kjetil, & Violante, Giovanni L. 2020. Optimal progressivity with age-dependent taxation. Journal of Public Economics, 104074. [26] Heckman, James J. 1976. The common structure of statistical models of truncation, sample selection and limited dependent variables and a simple estimator for such models. Pages 475–492 of: Annals of economic and social measurement, volume 5, number 4. NBER. [27] Heckman, James J. 1977. Sample selection bias as a specification error (with an application to the estimation of labor supply functions). Tech. rept. National Bureau of Economic Research. [28] Karabarbounis, Loukas, & Neiman, Brent. 2014. The global decline of the labor share. The Quarterly journal of economics, 129(1), 61–103. [29] Krusell, Per, Ohanian, Lee E, Rios-Rull, Jose-Victor, & Violante, Giovanni L. 2000. Capital-skill complementarity and inequality: A macroeconomic analysis. Econometrica, 68(5), 1029–1053. [30] Mendoza, Enrique G, Razin, Assaf, & Tesar, Linda L. 1994. Effective tax rates in macroeconomics: Cross-country estimates of tax rates on factor incomes and consumption. Journal of Monetary Economics, 34(3), 297–323. [31] Mirrlees, James A. 1971. An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. The review of economic studies, 38(2), 175–208. [32] Nobrega, Valter. 2020. Optimal Taxation and Investment-Specific Technological Change. [33] Trabandt, Mathias, & Uhlig, Harald. 2011. The Laffer curve revisited. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58(4), 305–327. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/101003 |