Groll, Thomas and Ellis, Christopher J. (2012): A simple model of the commercial lobbying industry.
This is the latest version of this item.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_40407.pdf Download (539kB) | Preview |
Abstract
In this paper we present a model of the behavior of commercial lobbying firms (such as the so-called K-Street lobbyists of Washington, D.C.). In contrast to classical special interest groups, commercial lobbying firms represent a variety of clients and are not directly affected by policy outcomes. They are hired by citizens, or groups of citizens, to advocate on their behalf to policymakers. In our analysis we address two basic questions; why do commercial lobbying firms exist, and what are the implications of their existence for social welfare? We answer the first part of this question by proposing that commercial lobbying firms possess a verification technology that allows them to improve the quality of information concerning the social desirability of policy proposals. This gives policymakers the incentive to allocate their scarce time to lobbying firms. Essentially it is this access to policymakers that lobbying firms sell to their clients. To address the question of social welfare we construct a simple general equilibrium model that includes commercial lobbying firms, and compare the equilibrium obtained under market provision of lobbying services to the first best optimum. We find that the market level of lobbying services can be socially either too large or too small, and characterize when each will be the case.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | A simple model of the commercial lobbying industry |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Lobbying; Influence Activities; Information Acquisition; Financial Contributions; Commercial Lobbying Firms; Political Participation |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D72 - Political Processes: Rent-Seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty > D82 - Asymmetric and Private Information ; Mechanism Design |
Item ID: | 40407 |
Depositing User: | Thomas Groll |
Date Deposited: | 01 Aug 2012 01:12 |
Last Modified: | 28 Sep 2019 22:12 |
References: | Austen-Smith, D. (1994). "Strategic Transmission of Costly Information", Econometrica, vol. 62(4), pp. 955-963. Austen-Smith, D. (1995). "Campaign Contributions and Access", American Political Science Review, vol. 89(3), pp. 263-280. Bennedsen, M. and Feldmann, S.E. (2002a). "Lobbying Legislatures", Journal of Political Economy, vol. 110(4), pp. 919-948. Bennedsen, M. and Feldmann, S.E. (2002b). "Lobbying and Legislative Organization: The Effect of the Vote of Confidence Procedure", Business and Politics, vol. 4(2), pp. 187-203. Bennedsen, M. and Feldmann, S.E (2006). "Informational Lobbying and Political Contributions", Journal of Public Economics, vol. 90(4-5), pp. 631-656. Bernheim, B.D. and Whinston, M.D. (1986). "Menu Auctions, Resource Allocation, and Economic Influence", Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 101(1), pp. 1-31. Bertrand, M., Bombardini, M. and Trebbi, F. (2011). "Is It Whom You Know or What You Know? An Empirical Assessment of the Lobbying Process", mimeo. Besley, T. and Coate, S. (2001). "Lobbying and Welfare in a Representative Democracy", Review of Economic Studies, vol. 68(1), pp. 67-82. Blanes i Vidal, J., Draca, M. and Fons-Rosen, C. (2011). "Revolving Door Lobbyists", American Economic Review, forthcoming. Bolton, P. and Dewatriport, M. (2005). Contract Theory, Cambridge MA: MIT Press. Buchanan, J. M. (1980). "Rent-Seeking and Profit-Seeking", in (J.M. Buchanan, R.D. Tollison and G. Tullock, eds), Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Theory, pp. 3-15, College Station TX: Texas A\&M University Press. Congleton, R.D., Hillman, A.L. and Konrad, K.A. (2008). 40 Years of Research on Rent Seeking, vol. 1-2, Berlin Germany: Springer. Chari, R., Hogan, J. and Murphy, G. (2010). Regulating Lobbying: A Global Comparison, Manchester UK: Manchester University Press. Crawford, V.P. and Sobel, J. (1982). "Strategic Information Transmission", Econometrica, vol. 50(6), pp. 1431-1451. Eggers, A. (2010). "Partisan Revolving Door", mimeo. Groll, T. and Ellis, C.J. (2012). "Dynamic Commercial Lobbying", mimeo. Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1994). "Protection for Sale", American Economic Review, vol. 84(4), 833-850. Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (2001). Special Interest Politics, Cambridge MA: MIT Press. Grossman, S.J., and Hart, O.D. (1983). "An Analysis of the Principal-Agent Problem", Econometrica, vol. 51(1), pp. 7-45. Holmstr\"om, B. (1979). "Moral Hazard and Observability", Bell Journal of Economics, vol. 10(1), pp. 74-91. House of Commons Public Administration Select Committee (2009). "Lobbying: Access and influence in Whitehall - First Report of Session 2008-09", vol. 1, London UK. House of Commons Public Administration Select Committee (2009). "PASC Calls for a Register of Lobbying Activity", press notice, 5 January 2009, http://www.parliament.uk. House of Representatives (1995). "Lobbying Disclosure Act - Report to Accompany H.R. 2564", 104th Congress 1st Session, Rept. 104-339 Part 1. Krueger, A.O. (1974). "The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society", American Economic Review, vol. 64(3), pp. 291-303. Krishna, V. and Morgan, J. (2001). "A Model of Expertise", Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 116(2), pp. 747-775. Laffont, J-J. and Martimort, D. (2002). The Theory of Incentives: The Principal-Agent Model, Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press. Laffont, J-J. and Tirole, J. (1990). "The Politics of Government Decision Making: Regulatory Institutions", Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, vol. 6(1), pp. 1-31. Lohmann, S. (1995). "Information Access and Contributions: A Signaling Model of Lobbying", Public Choice, vol. 85(3-4), pp. 267-284. Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1986). "Relying on the Information of Interested Parties", Rand Journal of Economics, vol. 17(1), pp. 18-32. Mirrlees, J.A. (1974). "Notes on Welfare Economics, Information and Uncertainty", in: (Balch, M., McFadden, D. and Wu, S., eds), Essays in Equilibrium Behaviour under Uncertainty, pp. 243-258, Amsterdam NL: North-Holland. Mirrlees, J.A. (1976). "The Optimal Structure of Incentives and Authority Within an Organization", Bell Journal of Economics, vol. 7(1), pp. 105-131. Olson, M. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action, Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press. Persson, T., and Tabellini, G. (2000). Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy, MIT Press: Cambridge, MA. Potters, J., and v. Winden, F. (1992). "Lobbying and Asymmetric Information", Public Choice, vol. 74(3), pp. 269-292. Senate Office for Public Records (2011). Lobbying Disclosure Act Guidance, Washington DC: U.S. Senate. The Center for Ethics in Government (2010). 50 State Chart: Contingency Fees, National Congress of State Legislators. Tullock, G. (1967). "The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft", Western Economic Journal, vol. 5(3), pp. 224-232. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/40407 |
Available Versions of this Item
-
A Simple Model of the Commercial Lobbying Industry. (deposited 25 Jan 2012 22:04)
- A simple model of the commercial lobbying industry. (deposited 01 Aug 2012 01:12) [Currently Displayed]