Battisti, Michele (2015): Present-biased preferences and optimal compensation schedules: a note.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_64818.pdf Download (214kB) | Preview |
Abstract
This paper presents a very simple model with present biased agents where optimal compensation schedules may be back-loaded, which is a characteristics of wage contracts we often observe in reality. There is large evidence that workers are often paid less than their marginal productivity early in their careers, and more than their marginal productivity later. In this model, back-loaded wage schedules emerge as a commitment device that allows to prevent sub-optimal consumption and labor supply patterns.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Present-biased preferences and optimal compensation schedules: a note |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Present biased preferences; optimal wages; commitment device |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D0 - General > D03 - Behavioral Microeconomics: Underlying Principles J - Labor and Demographic Economics > J3 - Wages, Compensation, and Labor Costs > J31 - Wage Level and Structure ; Wage Differentials |
Item ID: | 64818 |
Depositing User: | Dr Michele Battisti |
Date Deposited: | 05 Jun 2015 23:34 |
Last Modified: | 27 Sep 2019 23:36 |
References: | Ashraf, N., D. Karlan, and W. Yin (2006). Tying Odysseus to the mast: Evidence from a commitment savings product in the Philippines. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (2), 635-672. Cabrales, A., A. Calvo-Armengol, and N. Pavoni (2008). Social preferences, skill segregation, and wage dynamics. Review of Economic Studies 75 (1), p65-98. Dostie, B. (2011). Wages, productivity and aging. De Economist 159 (2), 139-158. Duffy, S. and J. Smith (2013). Preference for increasing wages: How do people value various streams of income? Judgment and Decision Making 8 (1), 74-90. Flabbi, L. and A. Ichino (2001). Productivity, seniority and wages: New evidence from personnel data. Labour Economics 8 (3), p359-387. Frank, R. H. and R. M. Hutchens (1993). Wages, seniority, and the demand for rising consumption profiles. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 21 (3), p251-276. Frey, B. S. and R. Jegen (2001). Motivation crowding theory. Journal of Economic Surveys 15 (5), p589-611. Fukao, K., R. Kambayashi, D. Kawaguchi, H. U. Kwon, Y. G. Kim, and I. Yokoyama (2006). Deferred compensation: Evidence from employer-employee matched data from japan. Hi-Statiscussion Paper Series 06-187. Grund, C. and D. Sliwka (2007). Reference-dependent preferences and the impact of wage increases on job satisfaction: Theory and evidence. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 163 (2), p313-335. Hellerstein, J. and D. Neumark (2007). Production function and wage equation estimation with heterogenous labor: Evidence from a new matched employer-employee dataset. NBER Chapters, in: Hard-to-Measure Goods and Services: Essays in Honor of Zvi Griliches, 31-71. Laibson, D. I. (1994). Hyperbolic Discounting and Consumption. Ph. D. thesis. Lazear, E. (1999). Personnel economics: Past lessons and future directions. Journal of Labor Economics 17 (2), 198-236. Lazear, E. P. (1981). Agency, earnings profiles, productivity, and hours restrictions. American Economic Review 71 (4), p606-620. Loewenstein, G. F. and N. Sicherman (1991). Do workers prefer increasing wage profiles?. Journal of Labor Economics 9 (1), 67-84. Medoff, J. L. and K. G. Abraham (1980). Experience, performance, and earnings. Quarterly Journal of Economics 95 (4), p703-736. Meier, S. and C. Sprenger (2010). Stability of time preferences. IZA Discussion Paper 4756. O'Donoghue, T. and M. Rabin (1999). Doing it now or later. American Economic Review 89 (1), 103-124. Salop, J. and S. Salop (1976). Self-selection and turnover in the labor market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 90 (4), 619-627. Smith, J. (2009). Cognitive dissonance and the overtaking anomaly: Psychology in the principal-agent relationship. Journal of Socio-Economics 38 (4), 684-690. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/64818 |