Cassette, Aurélie and Farvaque, Etienne (2015): A dirty deed done dirt cheap: reporting the blame of a national reform on local politicians.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_67031.pdf Download (1MB) | Preview |
Abstract
This paper tests the hypothesis that upper-level governments can transfer the accountability of the costs of a reform to a lower one. The reform of the school rhythm in France provides the ground for a verification of this hypothesis, as it was nationally decided and locally implemented, right before a municipal election. The results confirm that local incumbents have taken the blame of the reform, especially in larger cities and if they belong to the governing coalition. In this case, thus, the cost of the reform is borne twice by the lower level of government, financially and politically, offering a double gain to the government. That mayors who have announced a boycott of the reform have received electoral gains confirms the perception of the local cost of the reform.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | A dirty deed done dirt cheap: reporting the blame of a national reform on local politicians |
English Title: | A dirty deed done dirt cheap: reporting the blame of a national reform on local politicians |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Reforms, Elections, Municipalities, Reform |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D0 - General > D04 - Microeconomic Policy: Formulation, Implementation, and Evaluation D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D72 - Political Processes: Rent-Seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D78 - Positive Analysis of Policy Formulation and Implementation H - Public Economics > H7 - State and Local Government ; Intergovernmental Relations > H77 - Intergovernmental Relations ; Federalism ; Secession I - Health, Education, and Welfare > I2 - Education and Research Institutions > I28 - Government Policy |
Item ID: | 67031 |
Depositing User: | Pr. Etienne Farvaque |
Date Deposited: | 13 Oct 2015 04:38 |
Last Modified: | 30 Sep 2019 16:35 |
References: | Ai C. and Norton E.C., 2003, “Interaction terms in logit and probit models”, Economics Letters, 80, 123-129. Agnello L., Castro V., Jalles J. T., Sousa R. M., 2015, What determines the likelihood of structural reforms ?, European Journal of Political Economy, 37, 129-145. Agüero J. M., Beleche T., 2013, “Test-Mex: Estimating the effects of school year length on student performance in Mexico”, Journal of Development Economics, 103, 353-361. Alesina A., Drazen A., 1991, Why are stabilizations delayed? American Economic Review, 81, 1170–1188. Brown G.K. and Mergoupis T., 2010, “Treatment Interactions with Non-Experimental Data in Stata”, Stata Journal, 11 (4), pp. 545-555 Cassette, A., Farvaque, E., and Héricourt, J. (2013). “Two-round elections, one-round determinants? Evidence from the French municipal elections”, Public Choice, 156, 563-591. Croson, Rachel, and Uri Gneezy. 2009. "Gender Differences in Preferences." Journal of Economic Literature, 47(2): 448-74. Cukierman A., Tommasi M., 1998, "When Does It Take a Nixon to Go to China?", American Economic Review, 88(1), 180-97. Delvolvé N., Jeunier B., 1999, “Effets de la durée du week-end sur l’état cognitif de l’élève en classe au cours du lundi”, Revue Française de Pédagogie, 126, 111-120. Dewatripont, M., Roland, G., 1992, Economic reform and dynamic political constraints, Review of Economic Studies, 59, 703–730. Dewatripont, M., Roland, G., 1995, The design of reform packages under uncertainty, American Economic Review, 85, 1207–1223. Drazen A., Grilli V., 1993, The benefit of crises for economic reforms, American Economic Review, 83, 598–607. Dubois E. and Paty S., 2010, “Yardstick competition: which neighbours matter?”, The Annals of Regional Science, 44(3), 433-452 Froot, K. A. (1989). Consistent covariance matrix estimation with cross-sectional dependence and heteroskedasticity in financial data. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 24, 333–355. Fu Q., Li M., 2014, Reputation-concerned policy makers and institutional status quo bias, Journal of Public Economics, 110, 15-25. Joanis M., 2013. "Sharing the Blame? Local Electoral Accountability and Centralized School Finance in California," Economics and Politics, vol. 25(3), 335-359. Kikuchi N., 2014, “The effect of instructional time reduction on educational attainment: Evidence from the Japanese curriculum standards revision”, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 32,17-41. Norton, E., H. Wang, and C. Ai. 2004. Computing interaction effects and standard errors in logit and probit models. The Stata Journal 4: 154–167. Lora E., Olivera 2004, What makes reforms likely: Political economy determinants of reforms in Latin America , Applied Economics, 7, 99-135. OECD, 2014, PISA 2012 Results: What Students Know and Can do : Student Performance in Mathematics, Reading and Science (Volume I). Padovano F., Petrarca I., 2013, "When and how politicians take ‘scandalous’ decisions?," Constitutional Political Economy, 24(4), 336-351. Padovano F., Petrarca I., 2014, “Are the responsibility and yardstick competition hypotheses mutually consistent?”, European Journal of Political Economy, vol. 34, 459-477. Parinduri R. A., 2014, “Do children spend too much time in schools? Evidence from a longer school year in Indonesia”, Economics of Education Review, 41, 89-104. Rodrik D., 1996, Understanding economic policy reform. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 9–41. Saint-Paul G., 2010. "Endogenous Indoctrination: Occupational Choices, the Evolution of Beliefs and the Political Economy of Reforms", Economic Journal, 120, 325-353. Tandon S., 2012, Economic reform, voting, and local political intervention: Evidence from India, Journal of Development Economics, 97, 221-231. Tommasi M., Velasco A., 1996, "Where are we in the political economy of reform?", Journal of Economic Policy Reform, 1(2), 187-238. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/67031 |