Guha, Brishti (2016): Secret ballots and costly information gathering: the jury size problem revisited.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_73048.pdf Download (541kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Suppose paying attention during jury trials is costly, but that jurors do not pool information (as in contemporary Brazil, or ancient Athens). If inattentive jurors are as likely to be wrong as right, I find that small jury panels work better as long as identical jurors behave symmetrically. If not paying attention makes error more likely than not, jurors may co-ordinate on two different symmetric outcomes: a “high-attention” one or a “low attention” one. If social norms stigmatize shirking, jurors co-ordinate on the high-attention equilibrium, and a smaller jury yields better outcomes. However, increasing the jury up to a finite bound works better if norms are tolerant of shirking, in which case co-ordination on the low-attention outcome results. If the cost of attention is high, a bare majority of jurors pay attention, and efficiency increases in jury size up to a bound. The model also applies to elections and referendums.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Secret ballots and costly information gathering: the jury size problem revisited |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Jury size, pivotal voters, secret ballots, multiple equilibria, costly information. |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D72 - Political Processes: Rent-Seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty > D82 - Asymmetric and Private Information ; Mechanism Design K - Law and Economics > K4 - Legal Procedure, the Legal System, and Illegal Behavior > K40 - General |
Item ID: | 73048 |
Depositing User: | Dr Brishti Guha |
Date Deposited: | 17 Aug 2016 16:40 |
Last Modified: | 07 Oct 2019 10:54 |
References: | 1.Austen-Smith, D. and J.S Banks (1996): “Information Aggregation, Rationality, and the Condorcet jury theorem”, American Political Science Review 90:34-45. 2. Cai, H (2009): “Costly participation and heterogeneous preferences in informational committees”, RAND Journal of Economics 40:173-189. 3. Fedderson, T. and W. Pesendorfer (1998): “Convicting the Innocent: the inferiority of unanimous jury verdicts under strategic voting”, American Political Science Review 92:23-35. 4. Guha, B (2011): “Preferences, prisoners and private information: was Socrates rational at his trial?” European Journal of Law and Economics 31:249-264. 5.Hansen, M.H (1991): The Athenian democracy in the age of Demosthenes: structure, principles and ideology. Oxford, UK and Cambridge, USA: Blackwell. 6.Koriyama, Y. and B. Szentes (2009): “A resurrection of the Condorcet jury theorem”, Theoretical Economics 4:227-252. 7.Leib, E.J (2007): “A comparison of criminal jury decision rules in democratic countries”, Ohio State Journal of Criminal Law 5:629-644. 8.Martinelli, C (2006): “Would rational voters acquire costly information?” Journal of Economic Theory 129:225-251. 9.McCannon, B (2011): “Jury size in classical Athens: an application of the Condorcet jury theorem”, Kyklos 64:106-121. 10.McLean, I. and F. Hewitt (1994): Condorcet: Foundations of social choice and political theory. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. 11.Mukhopadhyaya, K (2003): “Jury size and the free rider problem”, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 19:24-44. 12.Persico, N (2004): “Committee design with endogenous information”, Review of Economic Studies 71:165-191. 13.Triossi, M (2013): “Costly information acquisition: is it better to toss a coin?” Games and Economic Behavior 82:169-191. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/73048 |