Azrieli, Yaron (2009): An axiomatic foundation for multidimensional spatial models of elections with a valence dimension.
This is the latest version of this item.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_17614.pdf Download (251kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Recent works on political competition incorporate a valence dimension into the standard spatial model. The analysis of the game between candidates in these models is typically based on two assumptions about voters' preferences. One is that valence scores enter the utility function of a voter in an `additively separable' way, so that the total utility can be decomposed into the `ideological utility' from the implemented policy (based on the Euclidean distance) plus the valence of the winner. The second is that all the voters identically perceive the platforms of the candidates and agree about their score on the valence dimension.
The goal of this paper is to axiomatize collections of preferences that satisfy these assumptions. Specifically, we consider the case where only the ideal point in the policy space and the ranking over candidates are known for each voter. We characterize the case where there are policies $x_1,...,x_m$ for the $m$ candidates and numbers $v_1,...,v_m$ representing valence scores, such that a voter with an ideal policy $y$ ranks the candidates according to $v_i-||x_i-y||^2$.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | An axiomatic foundation for multidimensional spatial models of elections with a valence dimension |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Elections; Spatial model; Valence; Euclidean preferences |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D72 - Political Processes: Rent-Seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior |
Item ID: | 17614 |
Depositing User: | Yaron Azrieli |
Date Deposited: | 01 Oct 2009 18:19 |
Last Modified: | 03 Oct 2019 04:42 |
References: | [1] Ansolabehere, S. and J. M. Snyder, JR (2000) Valence politics and equilibrium in spatial election models, Public Choice 51, 327-336. [2] Aragones, E. and T. R. Palfrey (2002) Mixed equilibrium in a Downasian model with a favored candidate, Journal of Economic Theory 103, 131-161. [3] Ash, P. F. and E. Bolker (1985) Recognizing Dirichlet tessellation, Geometria Dedicata 19, 175-206. [4] Ash, P. F. and E. Bolker (1986) Generalized Dirichlet tessellation, Geometria Dedicata 20, 209-243. [5] Ashkenazi, G. and E. Lehrer (2002) Relative utility, working paper. [6] Aurenhammer, F. (1987) Power diagrams: Properties, algorithms and applications, SIAM Journal on Computing 16, 78-96. [7] Azrieli, Y. and E. Lehrer (2007) Categorization generated by extended prototypes { an axiomatic approach, Journal of Mathematical Psychology 51, 14-28. [8] Bogomolnaia, A. and J. F. Laslier (2007) Euclidean preferences, Journal of Mathematical Economics 43, 87-98. [9] Boots, B., A. Okabe and K. Sugihara (1992) Spatial Tessellations, John Wiley and Sons Ltd, England. [10] Chambers, C. P. and T. Hayashi (2008) Choice and individual welfare, working paper. [11] Degan, A. (2007) Candidate valence: Evidence from consecutive presidential elections, International Economic Review 48, 457-482. [12] Degan, A. and A. Merlo (2009) Do voters vote ideologically?, Journal of Economic Theory 144, 1868-1894. [13] Dix, M. and R. Santore (2002) Candidate ability and platform choice, Economics letters 76, 189- 194. [14] Downs, A. (1957) An Economic Theory of Democracy, Harper, New York. [15] Eguia, J. X. (2008) Foundations of spatial preferences, working paper. [16] Enelow, J. and M. J. Hinich (1981) A new approach to voter uncertainty in the Downasian spatial model, American Journal of Political Science 25, 483-493. [17] Gersbach, H. (1998) Communication skills and competition for donors, European Journal of Political Economy 14, 3-18. [18] Gilboa, I. and D. Schmeidler (2001) A Theory of Case-Based Decisions, Cambridge University Press. [19] Gilboa, I. and D. Schmeidler (2003) A derivation of expected utility in the context of a game, Games and Economic Behavior 44, 184-194. [20] Groseclose, T. (2001) A model of candidate location when one candidate has a valence advantage, American Journal of Political Science 45, 862-886. [21] Hotelling, H. (1929) Stability in competition, Economic Journal 39, 41-57. [22] Kalandrakis, T. (2008) Rationalizable voting, working paper. [23] Kim, K. (2005) Valence characteristics and entry of a third party, Economics Bulletin 4, 1-9. [24] Knoblauch, V. (2009) Recognizing one{dimensional Euclidean preferences, Journal of Mathematical Economics, forthcoming. [25] Matousek, J. (2002) Lectures on Discrete Geometry, Springer-Verlag, New York, USA. [26] Myerson, R. B. (1995) Axiomatic derivation of scoring rules without the ordering assumption, Social Choice and Welfare 12, 59-74. [27] Schofield, N. (2007) The mean voter theorem: Necessary and su±cient conditions for convergent equilibrium, Review of Economic Studies 74, 965-980. [28] Smith, J. (1973) Aggregation of preferences with a variable electorate, Econometrica 41, 1027-1041. [29] Young, H. P. (1975) Social choice scoring functions, Siam Journal on Applied Mathematics 28, 824-838. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/17614 |
Available Versions of this Item
-
Characterization of multidimensional spatial models of elections with a valence dimension. (deposited 08 Apr 2009 14:15)
- An axiomatic foundation for multidimensional spatial models of elections with a valence dimension. (deposited 01 Oct 2009 18:19) [Currently Displayed]