Kisswani, Khalid (2010): OPEC and Political Considerations when Deciding on Oil Extraction. Forthcoming in: Journal of Economics and Finance
This is the latest version of this item.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_34629.pdf Download (464kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Two oil price shocks changed the pattern of cheap oil. The first was the Arab embargo on oil exports in 1973. Oil prices rose five fold. In 1978, the second was the fall of Shah Iran. Prices soared to $80-$100 a barrel in today‘s prices. In 1960, OPEC was established and since then it has been a considerable political and economical force in the oil market. Two thirds of the world‘s oil reserves belong to OPEC members. OPEC is accused of being responsible for most of the price increases due to their production cuts and market power. This paper provides a general framework to examine the role of OPEC in affecting oil prices through the extracted quantities. A mathematical model is developed to explore the objective function of OPEC, which includes economic and political considerations. The idea is that OPEC members consider both the political support of their citizens and profits when determining oil extraction rates. This support is represented by a ―harm function‖ which was added to the objective function of OPEC. The solution of the model lends some support for inclusion of this harm function, through which OPEC benefits from the cuts in production aimed at harming the western countries. For this harm function to be meaningful empirically, OPEC members should have a high harm indicator, αt. With high harm indicator values, OPEC harms itself financially. The results suggest that OPEC appears to be accepting considerable monetary setbacks to appease its citizens‘ taste for harming the West. At different discount rates, the monetary losses range from about 10-20%. Solving the mathematical model required estimation of the residual demand that OPEC faces plus the cost function that applies to OPEC production. This paper reports the results of these estimations.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | OPEC and Political Considerations when Deciding on Oil Extraction |
English Title: | OPEC and Political Considerations when Deciding on Oil Extraction |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | OPEC, optimal control, cost estimation, demand estimation, resource economics |
Subjects: | Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics ; Environmental and Ecological Economics > Q3 - Nonrenewable Resources and Conservation > Q32 - Exhaustible Resources and Economic Development C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C5 - Econometric Modeling > C51 - Model Construction and Estimation Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics ; Environmental and Ecological Economics > Q4 - Energy > Q41 - Demand and Supply ; Prices C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C2 - Single Equation Models ; Single Variables > C20 - General Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics ; Environmental and Ecological Economics > Q3 - Nonrenewable Resources and Conservation > Q31 - Demand and Supply ; Prices C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C0 - General > C02 - Mathematical Methods |
Item ID: | 34629 |
Depositing User: | Khalid Kisswani |
Date Deposited: | 11 Nov 2011 15:39 |
Last Modified: | 10 Oct 2019 13:39 |
References: | 1. Abel, A., (1990). Asset prices under habit formation and catching up with the Joneses. American Economic Review. 80(2), 38–42. 2. Adelman, M. A., Shahi, M., (1989). Oil Development-Operating Cost Estimates, 1955-1985. Journal of Energy economics. 11(1), 2-10. 3. Baltagi, B., Griffin, M., (1983). Gasoline Demand in the OECD- An Application of Pooling and Testing Procedures. European Economic Review. 22(2),117–137 4. Blum, U. C. H., Foos, G., Gaudry, M. J., (1988). Aggregate Time Series Gasoline Demand Models: Review of the Literature and New Evidence for West Germany. Transportation Research—A 22A (2), 75–88. 5. Chapman, D., Khanna, N., (2000). World Oil: the Growing Case for International Policy. Contemporary Economic Policy. 18(1), 1-13. 6. Chapman, D., Khanna, N., (2001). An Economic Analysis of Aspects of Petroleum and Military Security in the Persian Gulf. Contemporary Economic Policy. 19(4), 371-381. 7. Christensen, L. R., Jorgenson, D. W., Lau, L. J., (1973). Transcendental Logarithmic Production Frontiers. Review of Economics and Statistics. 55(1), 28-45. 8. Cynthia Lin, C. Y., (2008). Insights from a Simple Hotelling Model. Working paper, University of California at Davis. 9. Dahl, C., Sterner, T., (1990). The Pricing of and the Demand for Gasoline: A Survey of Models. Memorandum 132, Sweden: Goteberg University 10. Dahl, C. (1994). A survey of Energy Demand Elasticities for the Developing World. Journal of Energy and Development, 17(1), 1-47. 11. Eltony, M. N. , Al-Mutairi, N. H. , (1995). Demand for Gasoline in Kuwait: An Empirical Analysis Using Cointegration Techniques. Journal of Energy Economics. 17(3), 249–253. 12. Garbacz, C., (1989). Gasoline, Diesel and Motor-Fuel Demand in Taiwan. The Energy Journal. 10(2), 153–163. 13. Green, E. J, Porter, R. H., (1984). Noncooperative Collusion under Imperfect Price Information. Econometrica. 52(1), 87-100. 14. Griffin, J. M. , Teece, D. J. , (1982). OPEC Behavior and World Oil Prices. George Allen and Unwin, London. 15. Griffin, J. M., (1985). OPEC Behavior: a Test of Alternative Hypotheses. American Economic Review. 75 (5), 954-963. 16. Griffin, J. M. , Xiong, W. , (1997). The Incentive to Cheat: an Empirical Analysis of OPEC. Journal of Law & Economics. 40(2), 289-316. 17. Hammoudeh, S., (1996). Oil Price, Mean Reversion, and Zone Adjustment. Southern Economic Journal. 62 (2). 18. Heal, G., Barrow, M., (1980). The Relationship between Interest rates and Metal Prices Movements. Review of Economic Studies. 47(1), 161-181. 19. Herfindahl, O., (1967). Depletion and Economic Theory. In M.Gaffiney (ed.). Extractive Resources and Taxation. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press. 20. Horn, M., (2004). OPEC‘s Optimal Crude Oil Price. Energy Policy. 32 (2), 269-280. 21. Hotelling, H., (1933). The Economics of Exhaustible Resources. Journal of Political Economy. 39, 137–175. 22. Jones, C. T., (1990). OPEC Behavior under Falling Prices: Implications for Cartel Stability. The Energy Journal. 11 (3), 117-134. 23. Kaufmann, R. K., Karadeloglou, S., Marcelo P. S., (2004). Does OPEC Matter? An Econometric Analysis of Oil Prices. The Energy Journal. 25(4), 67-90 24. Krautkraemer, J. A., (1998). Nonrenewable Resource Scarcity. Journal of Economic Literature. 36 (4), 2065–2107. 25. Mabro, R., (1992). OPEC and the Price of Oil. The Energy Journal. 13 (2), 1-17 26. MacAvoy, P., (1982). Crude Oil Prices as Determined by OPEC and Market Fundamentals. Ballinger, Cambridge, MA. 27. Mazraati, M., Jazayeri, T., (2004). Oil Price Movements and Production Agreements. OPEC Review. 28 (3), 207-226. 28. McRae, R., (1994). Gasoline Demand in Developing Asian Countries. The Energy Journal. 15(1), 143–155. 29. Moazzami, B. , Anderson, F. J. , (1994). Modeling Natural Resource Scarcity Using the "Error-Correction" Approach. Canadian Journal of Economics. 27 (4), 801-12. 30. OPEC Annual Statistical Bulletins 31. Pindyck, R. S., (1978). Gains to Producers from the Cartelization of Exhaustible Resources. The Review of Economics and Statistics. 60(2), 238–251. 32. Polasky, S., (1992). The Private and Social Value of Information: Exploration for Exhaustible Resources. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 23 (1), 1–21. 33. Porter, R. H., (1983). Optimal Cartel Trigger Price Strategies. Journal of Economic Theory. 29 (2), 313-338. 34. Ramanathan, R., (1999). Short- and Long-Run Elasticities of Gasoline Demand in India: An Empirical Analysis Using Cointegration Techniques. Journal of Energy Economics. 21(4), 321–330. 35. Ramcharran, H., (2001). OPEC‘s Production Under Fluctuating Oil Prices: Further Test of the Target Revenue Theory. Energy Economics. 23 (6), 667-681. 36. Rauscher, M., (1991). OPEC and the Price of Petroleum: Theoretical Considerations and Empirical Evidence ―Studies in International Economics and Institutions‖. Springer-Verlag. Berlin, Heidelberg. 37. Salant, S. W., (1976). Exhaustible Resources and Industrial Structure: a Nash-Cournot Approach to the World Oil Market. Journal of Political Economy. 84 (5), 1079–1093. 38. Slade, M. E., (1982). Trends in Natural Resource Commodity Prices: an Analysis of the Time Domain. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 9(2), 122–137. 39. Smith, L. J., (2005). Inscrutable OPEC? Behavioral Tests of the Cartel Hypothesis. The Energy Journal. 26(1), 51-82. 40. Stiglitz, J. E., (1976). Monopoly and the Rate of Extraction of Exhaustible Resources. The American Economic Review. 66 (4), 655-661. 41. Tang, L., Hammoudeh, S., (2002). An Empirical Exploration of the World Oil Price under the Target Zone Model. Energy Economics. 24 (6), 577-596. 42. Wasserfallen, W., Guntensperger, H., (1988). Gasoline Consumption and the Stock of Motor Vehicles: An Empirical Analysis for the Swiss Economy. Journal of Energy Economics. 10(2), 276–282. 43. Watkins, G. C. , Streifel, S. S. , (1998). World Crude Oil Supply: Evidence from Estimating Supply Functions by Country, Journal of Energy Finance & Development. 3 (1), 23-49. 44. Wirl, F., (2008). Why Do Oil Prices Jump (or Fall). Energy Policy. 36 (3), 1029–1043 |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/34629 |
Available Versions of this Item
-
OPEC and political considerations when deciding on oil extraction. (deposited 01 Dec 2010 14:27)
- OPEC and Political Considerations when Deciding on Oil Extraction. (deposited 11 Nov 2011 15:39) [Currently Displayed]