Spiliopoulos, Leonidas (2008): Do repeated game players detect patterns in opponents? Revisiting the Nyarko & Schotter belief elicitation experiment.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_6666.pdf Download (569kB) | Preview |
Abstract
The purpose of this paper is to reexamine the seminal belief elicitation experiment by Nyarko and Schotter (2002) under the prism of pattern recognition. Instead of modeling elicited beliefs by a standard weighted fictitious play model this paper proposes a generalized variant of fictitious play that is able to detect two period patterns in opponents’ behavior. Evidence is presented that these generalized pattern detection models provide a better fit than standard weighted fictitious play. Individual heterogeneity was discovered as ten players were classified as employing a two period pattern detection fictitious play model, compared to eleven players who followed a non-pattern detecting fictitious play model. The average estimates of the memory parameter for these classes were 0.678 and 0.456 respectively, with five individual cases where the memory parameter was equal to zero. This is in sharp contrast to the estimates obtained from standard weighted fictitious play models which are centred on one, a bias introduced by the absence of a constant in these models. Non-pattern detecting fictitious play models with memory parameters of zero are equivalent to the win-stay/lose-shift heuristic, and therefore some sub jects seem to be employing a simple heuristic alternative to more complex learning models. Simulations of these various belief formation models show that that this simple heuristic is quite effective against other more complex fictitious play models.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Institution: | University of Sydney |
Original Title: | Do repeated game players detect patterns in opponents? Revisiting the Nyarko & Schotter belief elicitation experiment |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | learning; game theory; behavioral game theory; fictitious play; repeated games; mixed strategy; non-cooperative games; pattern recognition; pattern detection; experimental economics; beliefs; belief elicitation; strategic |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C9 - Design of Experiments C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C6 - Mathematical Methods ; Programming Models ; Mathematical and Simulation Modeling > C63 - Computational Techniques ; Simulation Modeling C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory > C73 - Stochastic and Dynamic Games ; Evolutionary Games ; Repeated Games C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory > C72 - Noncooperative Games |
Item ID: | 6666 |
Depositing User: | Leonidas Spiliopoulos |
Date Deposited: | 09 Jan 2008 01:39 |
Last Modified: | 01 Oct 2019 03:59 |
References: | Aizenstein, H., V. Stenger, J. Cochran, K. Clark, M. Johnson, R. Nebes, and C. Carter (2004). Regional Brain Activation during Concurrent Implicit and Explicit Sequence Learning. Cerebral Cortex 14, 199–208. Bar-Hillel, M. and W. Wagenaar (1991). The perception of randomness. Advances in Applied Mathematics 12 (4), 428–454. Binmore, K., J. Swierzbinski, and C. Proulx (2001). Does Minimax Work? An Experimental Study. Economic Journal 111 (473), 445–464. Bloomfield, R. (1994). Learning a mixed strategy equilibrium in the laboratory. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 25 (3), 411–436. Blume, A., D. DeJong, G. Neumann, and N. Savin (1999). Learning in sender-receiver games. University of Iowa working paper . Brown, J. N. and B. W. Rosenthal (1990). Testing the minimax hypothesis: A re-examination of o’neill’s game experiment. Econometrica 38, 1065–81. Cabrales, A. and W. Garcia-Fontes (2000). Estimating learning models from experimental data. University of Pompeu Fabra working paper . Camerer, C. (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton Uni- versity Press. Camerer, C. F. and T. Ho (1999). Experience-weighted attraction learning in normal-form games. Econometrica 67, 827–74. Cheung, Y. W. and D. Friedman (1997). Individual learning in normal form games: Some laboratory results. Games and Economic Behavior 19, 46–76. Chiappori, P. A., S. Levitt, and T. Groseclose (2002). Testing mixed strategy equilibria when players are heterogeneous: The case of penalty kicks in soccer. American Economic Review 92 (4), 1138– 1151. Cleeremans, A., A. Destrebecqz, and M. Boyer (1998). Implicit learning: news from the front. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 2 (10), 406–416. Clegg, B., G. DiGirolamo, and S. Keele (1998). Sequence learning. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 2 (8), 275–281. Davison, A. C. and D. V. Hinkley (1997). Bootstrap Methods and their Application. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge. Destrebecqz, A., P. Peigneux, S. Laureys, C. Degueldre, G. Del Fiore, J. Aerts, A. Luxen, M. van der Linden, and A. Cleeremans (2003). Cerebral correlates of explicit sequence learning. Cogn Brain Res 16, 391–8. Dorris, M. and P. Glimcher (2004). Activity in Posterior Parietal Cortex Is Correlated with the Relative Sub jective Desirability of Action. Neuron 44 (2), 365–378. Fisher, R. (1920). A mathematical examination of the methods of determining the accuracy of observation by the mean error and the mean square error. Monthly Notes of the Royal Astronomical Society 80, 758–770. Freeman, G. and J. Halton (1951). Note on an Exact Treatment of Contingency, Goodness of Fit and Other Problems of Significance. Biometrika 38 (1/2), 141–149. Fudenberg, D. and D. K. Levine (1998). The Theory of Learning in Games (Economics Learning and Social Evolution). Cambridge: MIT Press. 35 Gigerenzer, G. (2000). Adaptive thinking: Rationality in the real world. New York: Oxford University Press. Gigerenzer, G. and R. Selten (Eds.) (2001). Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Gomez, R. L. (1997). Transfer and complexity in artificial grammar learning. Cognitive Psychol- ogy 33, 154–207. Gorard, S. (2005). The advantages of the mean deviation. British Journal of Educational Stud- ies 53 (4), 417–30. Haruvy, E. and D. Stahl (2004). Deductive versus inductive equilibrium selection: experimental results. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 53 (3), 319–331. Huber, P. (1981). Robust Statistics. New York, John Wiley and Sons. Kagel, John H. Roth, A. E. (Ed.) (1995). The Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton University Press. Kahneman, D. and A. Tversky (1979). Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk. Econometrica 47 (2), 263–292. Martignon, L. and K. Laskey (1999). Simple Heuristics That Make Us Smart, pp. 169–188. Oxford University Press. Matheson, I. (1990). A critical comparison of least absolute deviation fitting(robust) and least squares fittings: the importance of error distributions. Computers & chemistry 14 (1), 49–57. Matlab (2007). Mathworks, Inc., Natick, MA. McKelvey, Richard D. Palfrey, T. R. (1995). Quantal response equilibria for normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior 7, 6–38. Miller, G. (1956). The magical number seven, plus or minus two. Psychological Review 63, 81–97. Mitchell, M. (1999). An Introduction to Genetic Algorithms (Fifth ed.). The MIT Press. Mitropoulos, A. (2001). On the measurement of the predictive success of learning theories in repeated games. Economics Working Paper Archive EconWPA. Nelder, J. A. and R. Mead (1965). A simplex method for function minimization. Computer Journal 7, 308–313. Nissen, M. and P. Bullemer (1987). Attentional requirements of learning: evidence from performance measures. Cognitive psychology 19 (1), 1–32. Nyarko, Y. and A. Schotter (2002). An experimental study of belief learning using elicited beliefs. Econometrica 70 (3), 971. O’Neill, B. (1987). Nonmetric test of the minimax theory of two-person zerosum games. In Proceed- ings of the National Academy of Sciences, Volume 84, pp. 2106–9. Palacios-Huerta, I. (2003). Professionals play minimax. Review of Economic Studies 70, 395–415. Papke, L. E. and J. M. Wooldridge (1996, nov). Econometric methods for fractional response variables with an application to 401 (k) plan participation rates. Journal of Applied Economet- rics 11 (6), 619–632. Platt, M. L. and P. Glimcher (1999). Neural correlates of decision variables in parietal cortex. Nature 400, 233–238. Rabin, M. (2002). Inference by believers in the law of small numbers. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(3), 775–816. 36 Rapoport, A. and D. Budescu (1997). Randomization in individual choice behavior. Psychological Review 104 (603-617). Remillard, G. (2007). Implicit learning of second-, third-, and fourth-order adjacent and nonadjacent sequential dependencies. The Quarterly Journal of Experimental Psychology 1. Remillard, G. and J. M. Clark (2001). Implicit learning of First-, Second-, and Third-Order Transi- tion Probabilities. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory and Cognition 27 (2), 483–498. Roth, A. E. and I. Erev (1995). Learning in Extensive-Form Games: Experimental Data and Simple Dynamic Models in the Intermediate Term. Games and Economic Behavior 8 (1), 164–212. Salmon, T. C. (2001). An Evaluation of Econometric Models of Adaptive Learning. Economet- rica 69 (6), 1597–1628. Shachat, J. and T. J. Swarthout (2004). Do we detect and exploit mixed strategy play by opponents? Mathematical Methods of Operations Research 59 (3), 359–373. Sidak, Z. (1967). Rectangular confidence regions for the means of multivariate normal distributions. Journal of the American Statistical Association 62, 626–633. Sonnemans, J. and T. Offerman (2001). Is the Quadratic Scoring Rule Really Incentive Compatible? University of Amsterdam manuscript . Spiliopoulos, L. (2008). Humans versus computer algorithms in repeated mixed strategy games. Walker, M. and J. Wooders (2001). Minimax play at wimbledon. American Economic Review , 1521–38. Wilson, H. (1978). Least squares versus minimum absolute deviations estimation in linear models. Decision Sciences 9, 322–335. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/6666 |
Available Versions of this Item
- Do repeated game players detect patterns in opponents? Revisiting the Nyarko & Schotter belief elicitation experiment. (deposited 09 Jan 2008 01:39) [Currently Displayed]