Garrod, Luke and Olczak, Matthew (2016): Collusion, Firm Numbers and Asymmetries Revisited.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_74352.pdf Download (1MB) | Preview |
Abstract
Despite the fact that competition law prohibits explicit cartels but not tacit collusion, theories of collusion often do not distinguish between the two. In this paper, we address this issue and ask: under which types of market structures are cartels likely to arise when firms can alternatively collude tacitly? To answer this question, we analyse an infinitely repeated game where firms with (possibly asymmetric) capacity constraints can make secret price cuts. Tacit collusion can involve price wars on the equilibrium path. Explicit collusion involves firms secretly sharing their private information in an illegal cartel to avoid such price wars. However, this runs the risk of sanctions. We find that, in contrast to the conventional wisdom but consistent with the available empirical evidence, cartels are least likely to arise in markets with a few symmetric firms, because tacit collusion is relatively more appealing in such markets. We discuss the implications for anti-cartel enforcement policy.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Collusion, Firm Numbers and Asymmetries Revisited |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | cartel, tacit collusion, imperfect monitoring, capacity constraints |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D4 - Market Structure, Pricing, and Design > D43 - Oligopoly and Other Forms of Market Imperfection D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty > D82 - Asymmetric and Private Information ; Mechanism Design K - Law and Economics > K2 - Regulation and Business Law > K21 - Antitrust Law L - Industrial Organization > L4 - Antitrust Issues and Policies > L44 - Antitrust Policy and Public Enterprises, Nonprofit Institutions, and Professional Organizations |
Item ID: | 74352 |
Depositing User: | Dr Matthew Olczak |
Date Deposited: | 09 Oct 2016 11:44 |
Last Modified: | 28 Sep 2019 22:03 |
References: | [1] Abreu, D., Pearce, D. and Stacchetti, E. (1986) “Optimal Cartel Equilibria with Imperfect Monitoring,” Journal of Economic Theory, 39(1), 251-269 [2] Abreu, D., Pearce, D. and Stacchetti, E. (1990) “Toward a Theory of Discounted Repeated Games with Imperfect Monitoring,” Econometrica, 58(5), 1041-1063 [3] Athey, S. and Bagwell, K. (2001) “Optimal Collusion with Private Information,” RAND Journal of Economics, 32(3), 428–465 [4] Athey, S. and Bagwell, K. (2008) “Collusion with Persistent Cost Shocks,” Econometrica, 76(3), 493–540 [5] Awaya, Y. and Krishna, V. (2014) “On Tacit versus Explicit Collusion,” mimeo, Penn State University [6] Bageri, V., Katsoulacos, Y. and Spagnolo, G. (2013) “The Distortive Effects of Antitrust Fines Based on Revenue,” The Economic Journal, 123 (572), 545-5 [7] Bos, I. and Harrington, J. (2010) “Endogenous Cartel Formation with Heterogeneous Firms,” RAND Journal of Economics, 41(1), 92–117 [8] Bos, I. and Harrington, J. (2015) “Competition Policy and Cartel Size,” International Eco- nomic Review, 56(1), 133-153 [9] Chen, Z. and Rey, P. (2013) “On the Design of Leniency Programs,” Journal of Law and Economics, 56(4), 917 - 957 [10] Compte, O., Jenny, F. and Rey, P. (2002) “Capacity Constraints, Mergers and Collusion,” European Economic Review, 46(1), 1-29 [11] Connor, J. (2010) “Recidivism Revealed: Private International Cartels 1991-2009” Compe- tition Policy International, 6(2), 101-127 [12] Davies, S. and Olczak, M. (2008) “Tacit versus Overt Collusion Firm Asymmetries and Numbers: What’s the Evidence?” Competition Policy International, 4(2), 175-200 [13] Davies, S., Olczak, M., and Coles, H. (2011) “Tacit Collusion, Firm Asymmetries and Num- bers: Evidence from EC Merger Cases,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 29(2), 221-31 [14] Dick, A. (1996) “When Are Cartels Stable Contracts?” Journal of Law and Economics, 39(1), 241–8 [15] Fonseca, M. and Normann, H.-T. (2008) “Mergers, Asymmetries and Collusion: Experi- mental Evidence,” Economic Journal, 118(1), 287-400 [16] Fonseca, M. and Normann, H.-T. (2012) “Explicit vs. Tacit Collusion – The Impact of Communication in Oligopoly Experiments,” European Economic Review, 56(8), 1759-1772 [17] Fraas, A., and D. Greer (1977) “Market Structure and Price Collusion: An Empirical Anal- ysis,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 26(1), 21–44 [18] Fudenberg, D. and Tirole, J. (1991), Game Theory, MIT Press [19] Garrod, L. and Olczak, M. (2016) “Collusion under Imperfect Monitoring with Asymmetric Firms,” MPRA Paper No. 70647, https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/70647/ [20] Green, E. and Porter, R. (1984) “Non-Cooperative Collusion under Imperfect Price Information,” Econometrica, 52, 87-100 [21] Grout, P. and Sonderegger, S. (2005) “Predicting Cartels,” A report for the Office of Fair Trading, Economic Discussion Paper 773 [22] Harrington, J. (2006) “How do Cartels Operate?” Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics, 2(1), 1-105 [23] Harrington, J. (2008) “Detecting Cartels,” in Buccirossi, P., (ed.), Handbook of Antitrust Economics, MIT Press [24] Harrington, J. and Chang, M.-H. (2015) “When Can We Expect a Corporate Leniency Program to Result in Fewer Cartels?,” Journal of Law and Economics, 58(2), 417-449 [25] Harrington, J. and Skrzypacz, A. (2011) “Private Monitoring and Communication in Cartels: Explaining Recent Collusive Practices,” American Economic Review, 101(6), 2425-2449 [26] Hay, G. and Kelley, D. (1974) “An Empirical Survey of Price Fixing Conspiracies” Journal of Law and Economics, 17(1), 13-38 [27] International Competition Network (2008) “Setting of Fines for Cartels in ICN Jurisdictions,” Report to the 7th ICN Annual Conference, Kyoto 34 [28] Ivaldi, M., Jullien, B., Rey, P., Seabright, P., and Tirole, J. (2003) “The Economics of Tacit Collusion,” Report for DG Comp, European Commission [29] Y. Katsoulacos, Y., Motchenkova, E. and Ulph, D. (2015) “Penalizing Cartels: The Case for Basing Penalties on Price Overcharge,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 42, 70-80 [30] Ku ̈hn, K.-U., (2012) “How Market Fragmentation Can Facilitate Collusion,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 10(5), 1116-1140 [31] Lambson, E. (1994) “Some Results on Optimal Penal Codes in Asymmetric Bertrand Su- pergames,” Journal of Economic Theory, 62(2), 444-468 [32] Levenstein, M. and Suslow, V. (2006) “What Determines Cartel Success?” Journal of Economic Literature, 44(1), 43-95 [33] Martin, S. (2006) “Competition Policy, Collusion and Tacit Collusion,” International Jour- nal of Industrial Organization, 24(6), 1299-1332 [34] Motta, M. (2004) Competition Policy: Theory and Practice, Cambridge University Press [35] Mouraviev, I. (2013) “Explicit Collusion under Antitrust Enforcement,” Center for Mathematical Economics Working Paper, no. 494 [36] Motta, M. and Polo, M. (2003) “Leniency Programs and Cartel Prosecution,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 21(3), 347-379 [37] Petit, L. (2012) “The Economic Detection Instrument of the Netherlands Competition Authority: The Competition Index,” NMa Working Papers, No. 6 [38] Posner, R. (1970) “A Statistical Study of Antitrust Enforcement,” Journal of Law and Economics, 13(2), 365–419 [39] Spagnolo, G. (2005) “Divide et Impera: Optimal Leniency Programs,” CEPR. Discussion Paper No. 4840 [40] Spector, D. (2015) “Facilitating Collusion by Exchanging Non-Verifiable Sales Reports,” PSE Working Papers no. 2015-07 [41] Stigler, G. (1964) “A Theory of Oligopoly,” Journal of Political Economy, 72, 44–61 [42] Symeonidis, G. (2003) “In Which Industries is Collusion More Likely? Evidence from the UK,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 51(1), 45–74 [43] Tirole, J. (1988) The Theory of Industrial Organisation, MIT Press [44] Vasconcelos, H. (2005) “Tacit Collusion, Cost Asymmetries, and Mergers,” RAND Journal of Economics, 36(1), 39-62 |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/74352 |