Guha, Brishti (2017): Should Jurors Deliberate?
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_79876.pdf Download (567kB) | Preview |
Abstract
Does the accuracy of verdicts improve or worsen if individual jurors on a panel are barred from deliberating prior to casting their votes? I study this question in a model where jurors can choose to exert costly effort to improve the accuracy of their individual decisions. I find that, provided the cost of effort is not too large, there is a threshold jury size above which it is better to allow jurors to deliberate. For panels smaller than this threshold, it is more effective to instruct jurors to vote on the basis of their private information, without deliberations, and to use a simple majority rule to determine the collective decision (regardless of the voting rule used with deliberations). The smaller the cost of paying attention, the larger the threshold above which the switch to allowing deliberations becomes optimal. However, if the unanimity rule had to be maintained under the no-deliberations system, it would be better to allow deliberation. The results apply to binary decision making in any committee where the committee members incur some effort in reviewing the evidence. Examples are tenure and promotion committees and some board of director meetings on issues such as whether to dismiss a CEO.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Should Jurors Deliberate? |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Jury deliberations, free riding, costly attention, secret voting, committees. |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D71 - Social Choice ; Clubs ; Committees ; Associations D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty > D82 - Asymmetric and Private Information ; Mechanism Design K - Law and Economics > K4 - Legal Procedure, the Legal System, and Illegal Behavior > K41 - Litigation Process |
Item ID: | 79876 |
Depositing User: | Dr Brishti Guha |
Date Deposited: | 26 Jun 2017 13:28 |
Last Modified: | 27 Sep 2019 13:18 |
References: | 1.Austen-Smith, D. and J.S Banks (1996): “Information Aggregation, Rationality, and the Condorcet jury theorem”, American Political Science Review 90:34-45. 2.Austen-Smith, D. and T.J Fedderson (2006): “Deliberation, Preference Uncertainty, and Voting Rules”, American Political Science Review 100:209-217. 3.Buechel, B and L. Mechtenburg (2016) “The Swing Voter’s curse in social networks,”, working paper. 4.Cai, H (2009): “Costly participation and heterogeneous preferences in informational committees”, RAND Journal of Economics 40:173-189. 5.Coughlan, P.J. (2000): “In defense of unanimous jury verdicts: mistrials, communication and strategic voting”, American Political Science Review 94:375-393. 6.Fedderson, T. and W. Pesendorfer (1998): “Convicting the Innocent: the inferiority of unanimous jury verdicts under strategic voting”, American Political Science Review 92:23-35. 7.Guha, B (2011): “Preferences, prisoners and private information: was Socrates rational at his trial?” European Journal of Law and Economics 31:249-264. 8.Guha, B. (2016): “Secret ballots and costly information gathering: the jury size problem revisited”, MPRA working paper #73048. 9.Hansen, M.H (1991): The Athenian democracy in the age of Demosthenes: structure, principles and ideology. Oxford, UK and Cambridge, USA: Blackwell. 10.Helland, E. and Y. Raviv (2008): “The optimal jury size when jury deliberation follows a random walk”, Public Choice 134:255-262. 11.Hummel, P (2012): “Deliberation in large juries with diverse preferences”, Public Choice 150: 595-608. 12.Koriyama, Y. and B. Szentes (2009): “A resurrection of the Condorcet jury theorem”, Theoretical Economics 4:227-252. 13.Leib, E.J (2007): “A comparison of criminal jury decision rules in democratic countries”, Ohio State Journal of Criminal Law 5:629-644. 14.Luppi, B. and F. Parisi (2013): “Jury size and the hung jury paradox”, Journal of Legal Studies 42: 399-422. 15.Martinelli, C (2006): “Would rational voters acquire costly information?” Journal of Economic Theory 129:225-251. 16.McCannon, B (2011): “Jury size in classical Athens: an application of the Condorcet jury theorem”, Kyklos 64:106-121. 17.McCannon, B. and P. Walker (2016): “Endogenous Competence and a Limit to the Condorcet Jury Theorem”, No (16-12), Department of Economics, West Virginia University. 18.Mukhopadhyaya, K (2003): “Jury size and the free rider problem”, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 19:24-44. 19.Neilson, W. and H. Winter (2008): “Votes based on protracted deliberations”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 67:308-321. 20.Persico, N (2004): “Committee design with endogenous information”, Review of Economic Studies 71:165-191. 21.Salerno, J.M and S.S Diamond (2010): “The promise of a cognitive perspective on jury deliberation”, Psychonomic Bulletin and Review 17: 174-179. 22.Triossi, M (2013): “Costly information acquisition: is it better to toss a coin?” Games and Economic Behavior 82:169-191. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/79876 |