Yuki, Kazuhiro (2014): Education, inequality, and development in a dual economy. Forthcoming in: Macroeconomic Dynamics
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_75750.pdf Download (597kB) | Preview |
Abstract
This paper develops a dynamic dual-economy model and examines how the long-run outcome of an economy depends on the initial distribution of wealth and sectoral productivity.
It is shown that, for fast transformation into a developed economy, the initial distribution must be such that extreme poverty is not prevalent so that most people can take education to acquire basic skills and the size of ”middle class” is enough so that an adequate number of people can access education to acquire advanced skills. Both conditions seem to have held in successful East Asian nations, where, as in the model economy undergoing such transformation, the fraction of workers with advanced skills rose greatly and inequalities between these workers and others fell over time.
In contrast, if the former condition holds but the latter does not, which would be the case for many nations falling into ”middle income trap”, consistent with facts, the fraction of workers with basic skills and the share of the modern sector rise, but inequality between workers with advanced skills and with basic skills worsens and the traditional sector remains for long periods. If the former condition does not hold, which would be true for poorest economies, the dual structure and large inequality between workers without basic skills and others persist for very long periods.
Consistently, Hanushek and Woessmann (2009) find that both the share of students with basic skills and that of top performance have significant effects on economic growth that are complementary each other.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Education, inequality, and development in a dual economy |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | dual economy, modernization, education, wealth distribution |
Subjects: | I - Health, Education, and Welfare > I2 - Education and Research Institutions > I25 - Education and Economic Development J - Labor and Demographic Economics > J3 - Wages, Compensation, and Labor Costs > J31 - Wage Level and Structure ; Wage Differentials O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O1 - Economic Development > O15 - Human Resources ; Human Development ; Income Distribution ; Migration O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O1 - Economic Development > O17 - Formal and Informal Sectors ; Shadow Economy ; Institutional Arrangements |
Item ID: | 75750 |
Depositing User: | Kazuhiro Yuki |
Date Deposited: | 23 Dec 2016 06:33 |
Last Modified: | 27 Sep 2019 16:38 |
References: | [1] Acemoglu, D. and F. Zilibotti (2001), ”Productivity differences,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(2), 563−606. [2] Akbulut, Rah¸san (2011), ”Sectoral changes and the increase in women’s labor force participation,” Macroeconomic Dynamics 15 (2): 240−264. [3] Alfo, M., G. Trovato, and R. J. Waldman (2008), ”Testing for country heterogeneity in growth models using a finite mixture apporach,” Journal of Applied Econometics 23, 487−514. [4] Banerjee, A., Newman A. (1998), ”Information, the dual economy, and development,” Review of Economic Studies 65 (4), 631−53. [5] Beck, T., A. Demirg¨u¸c-Kunt, and R. Levine (2007), ”Finance, inequality and the poor,” Journal of Economic Growth 12(1), 27−49. [6] Colclough, C., G. Kingdon, and H. Patrinos (2010), ”The changing pattern of wage returns to education and its implications,” Development Policy Review 28 (6), 733−747. [7] Deininger, K. and P. Olinto (2000), ”Asset distribution, inequality, and growth,” mimeo, World Bank. [8] Easterly, W. (2001), ”The middle class consensus and economic development,” Journal of Economic Growth 6 (4), 317−35. [9] Galor, O. (2005), ”From stagnation to growth: unified growth theory,” in P. Aghion and S. N. Durlauf eds., Handbook of Economic Growth Vol. 1A, Amsterdam: Elsevier, 171−293. [10] Galor, O. and J. Zeira (1993), ”Income distribution and macroeconomics”, Review of Economic Studies 60 (1), 35−52. [11] Galor, O. and O. Moav (2004), ”From physical to human capital accumulation: inequality in the process of development,” Review of Economic Studies 71(4), 1001−1026. [12] Galor, O. and O. Moav (2006), ”Das human-kapital: a theory of the demise of the class structure,” Review of Economic Studies 73(1), 85−117. [13] Galor, O., O. Moav, and D. Vollrath (2009), “Inequality in landownership, the emergence of human-capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence,” Review of Economic Studies 76, 143−179. [14] Gersback, Hans and Lars-H. R. Siemens (2010), ”Land reforms and economic development,”Macroeconomic Dynamics 14 (4): 527−547 [15] Hansen, G. D. and E. C. Prescott (2002), ”Malthus to Solow,” American Economic Review 92 (4), 1205−1217. [16] Hanushek, E. A. and L. Woessmann (2008), ”The role of cognitive skills in economic development,” Journal of Economic Literature 46 (3), 607−668. [17] Hanushek, E.A. and L. Woessmann, (2009), ”Do better schools lead to more growth? Cognitive skills, economic outcomes, and causation,” NBER Working Paper 14633. [18] Hippe, R. and J. Baten (2012), ”‘Keep them ignorant.’ Did inequality in land distribution delay regional numeracy development?” mimeo, University of Tuebingen. [19] La Porta, R. and A. Shleifer (2008), ”The unofficial economy and economic development,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 35 (2), 275−352. [20] Lucas, R.E. Jr. (2004),“Life earnings and rural-urban migration,” Journal of Political Economy 112 1(2), S29−S59. [21] Kongsamut, P., S. Rebelo, and D. Xie (2001), ”Beyond balanced growth,” Review of Economic Studies 68 (4), 869−82. [22] Laitner, J. (2000), ”Structural change and economic growth,” Review of Economic Studies 67 (3), 545−61. [23] McDonald, Stuart and Jie Zhang (2012), ”Income inequality and economic growth with altruistic bequests and human capital investment,” Macroeconomic Dynamics 16 (S3), 331−354. [24] Ngai, R. and C. Pissarides (2007), ”Structural change in a multi-sector model of growth,” American Economic Review 97 (1), 429−443. [25] OECD (2009), Is Informal Normal? Towards More and Better Jobs, OECD, Paris. [26] Owen, A. L., J. Videras, and L. Davis (2009), ”Do all countries follow the same growth process?,” Journal of Economic Growth 14, 265−286. [27] Proto, E. (2007), ”Land and the transition from a dual to a modern economy,” Journal of Development Economics 83, 88−108. [28] Psacharopoulos, G. and Patrinos, H. A. (2004), ”Returns to investment in education: A further update,” Education Economics 12 (2), 111-134. [29] Rahman, Ahmed S. (2013), ”The road not taken: what is the “appropriate” path to development when growth is unbalanced?,” Macroeconomic Dynamics 17 (4), 747−778. [30] Ray, D. (1998), Development Economics, Princeton University Press, Princeton. [31] van Paap, R., Franses, P.H., and Dijk, D. (2005), ”Does Africa grows lower than Asia, Latin America and the Middle East? Evidence from a new data-based classification method,” Journal of Development Economics 77, 553−570. [32] Vollrath, Dietrich (2009), ”The dual economy in long-run development,” Journal of Economic Growth 14, 287−312. [33]Wang, P. and D. Xie (2004), ”Activation of a modern industry,” Journal of Development Economics 73 (2), 393−410. [34]Weil, D. (2013), Economic Growth, third edition, Pearson Education, Harlow. [35]Wood, A. (1994), North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World, Oxford University Press, Oxford. [36] Yuki, K. (2007), ”Urbanization, informal sector, and development,” Journal of Development Economics 84, 76−103. [37] Yuki, K. (2008), ”Sectoral shift, wealth distribution, and development,” Macroeconomic Dynamics 12 (4), 527−559. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/75750 |