Ray, Sourav and Wang, Li and Levy, Daniel and Bergen, Mark (2019): Pricing Better.
PDF
MPRA_paper_95596.pdf Download (442kB) |
Abstract
Electronic shelf label (ESL) is an emerging price display technology around the world. While these new technologies require non-trivial investments by the retailer, they also promise significant operational efficiencies in the form of savings in material, labor and managerial costs. The presumed benefits of ESL, for example, tend to be focused around lower price adjustment costs (PAC), also known as menu costs. However, ESL not only can save PAC but may also enable the retailer to price “better,” generating greater value for the transacting parties. Thus, ESL’s strategic impact for retailers occurs between claiming these presumed efficiencies and realizing the value generating potential. Using transactions data from a longitudinal field experiment, we assess such impact of ESL by studying how it shapes retail pricing practices and outcomes. Our general finding is that ESL plays an enabling role to the retailer’s strategy – thereby enhancing the retailer’s sales and revenues. The price adjustment efficiencies of ESL allows retailers to do better waste management, price discovery, as well as leveraging value in information for consumers. However, ESL’s impact on prices is nuanced, based on the retail strategy (EDLP, HI-LO) being used. Papers quantifying emerging technologies’ impact on retail outcomes are sparse, even fewer investigating their role in pricing. To the best of our knowledge, ours is the first study to explore and quantify how ESL interacts with retail strategy to affect retail pricing practices and retail outcomes.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Pricing Better |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | Retailing; Pricing; EDLP; HI-LO; Dynamic Capability; Menu Costs; Price Adjustment; Price Elasticity; Price Discovery |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C9 - Design of Experiments > C93 - Field Experiments D - Microeconomics > D2 - Production and Organizations > D22 - Firm Behavior: Empirical Analysis D - Microeconomics > D4 - Market Structure, Pricing, and Design > D40 - General E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics > E3 - Prices, Business Fluctuations, and Cycles > E31 - Price Level ; Inflation ; Deflation L - Industrial Organization > L1 - Market Structure, Firm Strategy, and Market Performance > L10 - General L - Industrial Organization > L8 - Industry Studies: Services > L81 - Retail and Wholesale Trade ; e-Commerce M - Business Administration and Business Economics ; Marketing ; Accounting ; Personnel Economics > M3 - Marketing and Advertising > M31 - Marketing O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth > O3 - Innovation ; Research and Development ; Technological Change ; Intellectual Property Rights > O33 - Technological Change: Choices and Consequences ; Diffusion Processes |
Item ID: | 95596 |
Depositing User: | Daniel Levy |
Date Deposited: | 19 Aug 2019 10:37 |
Last Modified: | 30 Sep 2019 11:49 |
References: | Adams, Brian, and Kevin Williams (2019), “Zone Pricing in Retail Oligopoly,” American Economic Journal: Micro 11(1), 124–156. Aghion, P., P. Bolton, C. Harris, and B. Jullien (1991), “Optimal Learning by Experimentation,” Review of Economic Studies 58, 621–654. Alvarez, Fernando, and Francesco Lippi (2014), “Price Setting with Menu Cost for Multiproduct Firms,” Econometrica 82(1), 89–135. Argente, David, and Chen Yeh (2016), “A Menu Cost Model with Price Experimentation,” manuscript, the University of Chicago. Bachmann, Rüdiger, and Giuseppe Moscarini (2011), “Business Cycles and Endogenous Uncertainty,” Economic Dynamics Meeting Papers, No. 36. Ball, Laurence, and N. Gregory Mankiw (1994), “A Sticky-Price Manifesto,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 127–152. Balvers, R. and T. Cosimano (1993), “Periodic Learning about a Hidden State Variable,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 17, 805–827. Barro, Robert J. (1972), “A Theory of Monopolistic Price Adjustment,” Review of Economic Studies 39(1), 17–26. Baudry, L., H. Le Bihan, P. Sevestre, and S. Tarrieu (2007), “What Do Thirteen Million Price Records Have to Say about Consumer Price Rigidity?” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 69(2), 139–183. Bergen, M., D. Levy, S. Ray, P. Rubin, and B. Zeliger (2008), “When Little Things Mean a Lot: on the Inefficiency of Item Pricing Laws,” Journal of Law and Economics 24, 491–539. Bolton, Ruth, and Venkatesh Shankar (2018), “Emerging Retailer Pricing Trends and Practices,” in the Handbook of Research on Retailing, Edited by Katrijn Gielens and Els Gijsbrechts (New York, NY: Edward Elgar Publishing), pp. 104–131. Campbell, Jeffrey, and Benjamin Eden (2014), “Rigid Prices: Evidence from US Scanner Data,” International Economic Review 55(2), 423–442. Cavallo, Alberto (2018), “Scraped Data and Sticky Prices,” Review of Economics Statistics 100(1), 105–119. DellaVigna, Stefano, and Matthew Gentzkow (2019), “Uniform Pricing in US Retail Chains,” Quarterly Journal of Economics (forthcoming). Dhyne, Emmanuel and Jerzy Konieczny (2007) “Temporal Distribution of Price Changes: Staggering in the Large and Synchronization in the Small,” Working Paper Series 01-07, Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis. Dutta, S., M. Bergen, D. Levy, and R. Venable (1999), “Menu Costs, Posted Prices, and Multiproduct Retailers,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 31, 683–703. Dutta, S., M. Zbaracki, and M. Bergen (2003), “Pricing Process as a Capability: a Resource-Based Perspective,” Strategic Management Journal 24(7), 615–630. Eisenhardt, Kathleen M., Martin, Jeffrey A. (2000), “Dynamic Capabilities: What Are They?” Strategic Management Journal 21, 1105–1121. Gedenk, K., Neslin, S. A., & Ailawadi, K. L. (2010). “Sales Promotion.” In M. Krafft, and M. K Mantrala (Eds.), Retailing in the 21st Century. (Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg), pp. 345–360. Grewal, D., Ailawadi, K. L., Gauri, D., Hall, K., Kopalle, P., and Robertson, J. R. (2011), “Innovations in Retail Pricing and Promotions,” Journal of Retailing 87(S1), 43–52. Garaus, Marion, Elisabeth Wolfsteiner, and Udo Wagner (2016), “Shoppers’ Acceptance and Perceptions of Electronic Shelf Labels,” Journal of Business Research 69, 3687–3692. Guadalupi, Carla (2014), “Strategic Experimentation and Price Signaling: Low Prices Signal High Quality,” manuscript. Hallberg, Niklas (2017), “The Micro-Foundations of Pricing Strategy in Industrial Markets: A Case Study in the European Packaging Industry,” Journal of Business Research 76, 179–88. Karadi, Peter and Adam Reiff (2012), “Large Shocks in Menu Cost Models,” Working Paper No. 1453, European Central Bank, Frankfurt. Keil, Sev, David Reibstein, and Dick Wittink (2001), “The Impact of Business Objectives and the Time Horizon of Performance Evaluation on Pricing Behavior,” International Journal of Research in Marketing 18(1-2), 67–81. Lach, Saul and Daniel Tsiddon (1996), “Staggering and Synchronization in Price-Setting: Evidence from Multiproduct Firms,” American Economic Review 86(5), 1175–1196. Lach, Saul and Daniel Tsiddon (2007), “Small Price Changes and Menu Costs,” Managerial and Decision Economics 28(7), 649–656. Levy, D., Bergen, M., Dutta, S., and Venable, R. (1997), “The Magnitude of Menu Costs: Direct Evidence from Large US Supermarket Chains,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 791–825. Levy, D., Dutta, S., Bergen, M., and Venable, R. (1998), “Price Adjustment at Multiproduct Retailers,” Managerial and Decision Economics 19, 81–120. Levy, D., G. Müller, H. Chen, M. Bergen, and S. Dutta (2010), “Holiday Price Rigidity and Cost of Price Adjustment,” Economica 77, 172–198. Mankiw, N. Gregory (1985), “Small Menu Costs and Large Business Cycles: a Macroeconomic Model of Monopoly,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, 529–39. Midrigan, V. (2011), “Menu Costs, Multi-Product Firms, and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Econometrica 79, 1139–1180. Ray, S., H. Chen., M. Bergen, and D. Levy (2006), “Asymmetric Wholesale Pricing: Theory and Evidence,” Marketing Science 25, 131–54. Ray, Sourav, Charles Wood, and Paul Messinger (2012), “Multicomponent Systems Pricing: Rational Inattention and Downward Rigidities,” Journal of Marketing 76, 1–17. Research and Markets (2017a), “Global Electronic Shelf Label Market 2018-2022.” ID: 4447181. Retrieved July 21, 2019 from http://tiny.cc/mu209y. Research and Markets (2017b), “Electronic Shelf Labels Market in the US 2017-2021.” ID: 4225889. Retrieved July 21, 2019 from http://tiny.cc/8n209y. Rotemberg, Julio J. (1982), “Sticky Prices in the United States,” Journal of Political Economy 90, 1187–211. Rotemberg, Julio J. (1987), “The New Keynesian Microfoundations,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 69–104. Rustichini, Aldo, and Asher Wolinksy (1995), “Learning about Variable Demand in the Long Run,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19, 1283–1292. Sheshinski, Eytan, and Yoram Weiss (1977), “Inflation and Costs of Price Adjustments,” Review of Economic Studies 44, 287–303. Slade, Margaret (1998), “Optimal Pricing with Costly Adjustment: Evidence from Retail-Grocery Prices,” Review of Economic Studies 65, 87–107. Soutjis, Bastien, Franck Cochoy, and Johan Hagberg (2017), “An Ethnography of Electronic Shelf Labels: The Resisted Digitalization of Prices in Contemporary Supermarkets,” Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 39, 296–304. Zbaracki, M., M. Bergen, and D. Levy (2007), ‘‘The Anatomy of a Price Cut: Discovering Organization Sources of the Cost of Price Adjustment,’’ manuscript, Bar-Ilan University and Emory University. Zbaracki, M., M. Ritson, D. Levy, S. Dutta, and M. Bergen (2004), ‘‘Managerial and Customer Costs of Price Adjustment: Direct Evidence from Industrial Markets,’’ Review of Economics and Statistics 86, 514–533. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/95596 |