Rodet, Cortney Stephen (2013): Seniority, Information and Electoral Accountability.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_49863.pdf Download (240kB) | Preview |
Abstract
This paper addresses the impact information has on electoral accountability in a legislative system based on seniority using laboratory experiments. A purely rational choice perspective of a simple voting environment implies that information is inconsequential when seniority is exceptionally valuable. Seniority advantage presents the opportunity to shirk at the expense of voters. I contrast the rational choice perspective to behavioral considerations of trust, betrayal and expectations. Voter information about incumbent behavior is varied across experimental treatments, and I find that information leads to accountability when voters can compare their own incumbent’s behavior to the behavior of others. Moreover, information deters incumbent shirking.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Seniority, Information and Electoral Accountability |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | voting, experiments, information, seniority, principal-agent |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C9 - Design of Experiments > C91 - Laboratory, Individual Behavior C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C9 - Design of Experiments > C92 - Laboratory, Group Behavior D - Microeconomics > D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making > D72 - Political Processes: Rent-Seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior D - Microeconomics > D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty > D89 - Other |
Item ID: | 49863 |
Depositing User: | Cortney Stephen Rodet |
Date Deposited: | 17 Sep 2013 02:56 |
Last Modified: | 08 Oct 2019 16:30 |
References: | Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., & Renner, E. (2000). The moonlighting game: An experimental study on reciprocity and retribution. Journal of Economc Behavior and Organization, 265-277. Alvarez, R. Michael and Jason L. Saving. 1997. “Congressional Committees and the Political Economy of Federal Outlays,” Public Choice 92: 55-73. Arceneaux, Kevin. 2006. “The Federal Face of Voting: Are Elected Officials Held Accountable for the Functions Relevant to Their Office?” Political Psychology 27: 731-754. Baron, David P. and John A. Ferejohn. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures,” The American Political Science Review 83: 1181-1206. Barro, Robert J. 1973. “The control of politicians: an economic model,” Public Choice 14: 19-42. Bernhardt, Dan, Sangita Dubey and Eric Hughson. 2004. “Term Limits and Pork Barrel Politics,” Journal of Public Economics 88: 2383-2422. Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 122-142. Besley Timothy and Robin S. L. Burgess. 2002. “The Political Economy of Government Responsiveness: Theory and Evidence from India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 1415-1451. Besley, Timothy and Anne Case. 1995. “Incumbent behavior: Vote-seeking, tax-setting, and yardstick competition.” The American Economic Review 85: 25-45. Besley, Timothy and Andrea Prat. 2006. “Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability.” The American Economic Review 96: 720-736. Buchanan, James M., and Roger D. Congleton. 1994. “The incumbency dilemma and rent extraction by legislators.” Public Choice 79: 47-60. Camerer, Colin. 2003. Behavioral Game Theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Chari, Varadarajan V., Larry E. Jones, and Ramon Marimon. 1997. “The Economics of Split-ticket Voting in Representative Democracies.” The American Economic Review 957-976. Charness, Gary and Matthew Rabin. 2002. “Understanding Social Preferences with Simple Tests,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 817-869. Chen, Kong-Pin, and Emerson M.S. Niou. 2005. “Term Limits as a Response to Incumbency Advantage,” The Journal of Politics 67: 390-406. Collier, Kenneth, Peter C. Ordeshook and Kenneth Williams. 1989. “The Rationally Uninformed Electorate: Some Experimental Evidence,” Public Choice 60: 3-29. Dana, J., Weber, R. A., & Kuang, J. X. (2007). Exploiting moral wiggle room: experiments demonstrating an illusory preference for fairness. Economic Theory, 67-80. Djankov, Simeon, Caralee McLiesh, Tatiana Nenova, and Andrei Shleifer. 2003. “Who Owns the Media?” Journal of Law and Economics 46: 341-381. Downs, Anthony. 1957. “An Economic Theory of Political Action in a Democracy,” The Journal of Political Economy 65: 135-150. Fallis, David S., Scott Higham and Kimberly Kindy. 2012. “Congressional earmarks sometimes used to fund projects near lawmakers’ properties,” The Washington Post, February 7. Accessed February 7, 2012. http://www.washingtonpost.com/investigations/congressional-earmarks-sometimes-used-to-fund-projects-near-lawmakers-properties/2012/01/12/gIQA97HGvQ_story.html Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2008). Testing theories of fairness - Intentions matter. Games and Economic Behavior, 62, 287-303. Ferraz, Claudio and Frederico Finan. 2008. “Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effects of Brazil’s Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 123: 703-745. Fischbacher, Urs. 2007. “Z-Tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-made Economic Experiments,” Experimental Economics 10(2): 171-178. Friedman, John N. and Richard T. Holden. 2009. “The Rising Incumbent Reelection Rate: What’s Gerrymandering Got to Do With It?” The Journal of Politics 71: 593- 611. Guerra, G., & Zizzo, D. J. (2004). Trust responsiveness and beliefs. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 25-30. Higham, Scott, Kimberly Kindy and David S. Fallis. 2012. “Capitol Assets: Some legislators send millions to groups connected to their relatives,” The Washington Post, February 7. Accessed February 7, 2012. http://www.washingtonpost.com/politics/congress/capitol-assets-some-legislators-send-millions-to-groups-connected-to-their-relatives/2012/01/10/gIQAyrzdxQ_story.html Holcombe, Randall G. 1989. “A note on Seniority and Political Competition,” Public Choice 61: 285-288. Levitt, Steven D. and James M. Snyder. 1997. “The Impact of Federal Spending on House Election Outcomes,” The Journal of Political Economy 105: 30-53. Koehler, J. J., & Gershoff, A. D. (2003). Betrayal aversion: When agents of protection become agents of harm. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 244-261. McCabe, K. A., Rigdon, M. L., & Smith, V. L. (2003). Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 52(2), 267-275. McKelvey, Richard D. and Raymond Riezman. 1992. “Seniority in Legislatures,” The American Political Science Review 86: 951-965. McMillan, John and Pablo Zoido. 2004. “How to Subvert Democracy: Montesinos in Peru,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 18: 69-92. Ostrom, E., & Walker, J. (2002). Trust and Reciprocity: Interdisciplinary Lessons for Experimental Research. New York: Russell Sage. Pelligra, V. (2010). Trust responsiveness. On the dynamics of fiduciary interactions. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 653-660. Prat, Andrea. 2005. “The Wrong Kind of Transparency,” The American Economic Review 95: 862-877. Rigdon, M. L., McCabe, K. A., & Smith, V. L. (2007). Sustaining cooperation in trust games. The Economic Journal, 117(522), 991-1007. Stein, Robert M. and Kenneth N. Bickers. 1994. “Congressional Elections and the Pork Barrel,” The Journal of Politics 56: 377-399. Strömberg, David. 2004. “Radio’s Impact on Public Spending,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119: 189-221. Weingast, Barry R. and William J. Marshall. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets,” The Journal of Political Economy 96: 132-163. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/49863 |