Cabo, Francisco and Martín-Román, Ángel L. (2017): Dynamic collective bargaining. Frictional effects under open-shop industrial relations.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_77562.pdf Download (581kB) | Preview |
Abstract
A dynamic Stackelberg game analyzes collective bargaining between a trade union (leader) and a firm (follower) in a monopoly union model. Frictional effects (FE) for the firm encompass symmetric adjustment costs linked to the number of hired and fired workers, plus a wage-dependent term (assuming wage-dependent hiring costs and wage discrimination against newcomers). The union faces marginally increasing costs in firings and marginally decreasing benefits from hirings. The two-part FE for the firm, the FE for the union, or both jointly considered differently affect employment and wages. Interestingly, standard adjustment costs increase hirings, even while the union reduces wages.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Dynamic collective bargaining. Frictional effects under open-shop industrial relations |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | dynamic labor demand, collective wage bargaining, monopoly union model, adjustment costs, Stackelberg differential game |
Subjects: | C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C6 - Mathematical Methods ; Programming Models ; Mathematical and Simulation Modeling > C61 - Optimization Techniques ; Programming Models ; Dynamic Analysis C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods > C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory > C73 - Stochastic and Dynamic Games ; Evolutionary Games ; Repeated Games J - Labor and Demographic Economics > J2 - Demand and Supply of Labor > J23 - Labor Demand J - Labor and Demographic Economics > J5 - Labor-Management Relations, Trade Unions, and Collective Bargaining > J51 - Trade Unions: Objectives, Structure, and Effects |
Item ID: | 77562 |
Depositing User: | Ángel Martín-Román |
Date Deposited: | 17 Mar 2017 16:50 |
Last Modified: | 02 Oct 2019 16:43 |
References: | Abowd, J. M., and Kramarz, F. (2003), “The costs of hiring and separations," Labor Economics 10(5), 499-530. Başar, T and G.K. Olsder (1982), Dynamic Non-cooperative Game Theory, Academic Press, New York. Bentolila, S., and Bertola, G. (1990), “Firing costs and labor demand: how bad is eurosclerosis?," The Review of Economic Studies, 57(3), 381-402. Bentolila, S., and Saint-Paul, G. (1994), “A model of labor demand with linear adjustment costs," Labor Economics, 1(3), 303-326. Bertola, G. (1990), “Job security, employment and wages," European Economic Review, 34(4), 851-879. Bertola, G., and Rogerson, R. (1997), “Institutions and labor reallocation," European Economic Review, 41(6), 1147-1171. Blanchard, O. J. (2005), Macroeconomics, 4th ed, Prentice Hall. Boeri, T., and Van Ours, J. (2013), The Economics of Imperfect Labor Markets, Princeton University Press. Booth, A. L. (1995), The Economics of the Trade Union, Cambridge University Press. Booth, A. L. (2014), “Wage determination and imperfect competition," Labour Economics, 30, 53-58. Cahuc, P., Carcillo, S., and Zylberberg, A. (2014), Labor economics, MIT press. Chang, C. C., and Stefanou, S. E. (1988), “Specification and estimation of asymmetric adjustment rates for quasi-fixed factors of production," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 12(1), 145-151. Chang, J. J., and Lai, C. C. (1997), “Union membership and employment dynamics with endogenous union density," Economics Letters, 57(1), 119-125. Chang, J. J., Shaw, M. F., and Lai, C. C. (2007), “A “Managerial" trade union and economic growth," European Economic Review, 51(2), 365-384. Dias da Silva, A., and Turrini, A. (2015), “Precarious and less well paid? Wage differences between permanent and fixed-term contracts across the EU," IZA Policy Paper, No. 105. Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). Dittrich, M., and Schirwitz, B. (2011a). “Union membership and employment dynamics: A note," Economics Letters, 110(1), 38-40. Dittrich, M., and Schirwitz, B. (2011b), “Unions-the bigger, the worse? Centralization and the scope of bargaining," Journal of Economic Research, 16(3), 231-255. Dobbelaere, S., and Luttens, R. I. (2016), “Gradual collective wage bargaining," Labour Economics, 40, 37-42. Dockner, E.J., S. Jørgensen, N.V. Long, and G. Sorger (2000), Differential Games in Economics and Management Science, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Eisner, R., Strotz, R. H., and Post, G. R. (1963), Determinants of business investment, Prentice-Hall. Goux, D., Maurin, E., and Pauchet, M. (2001), “Fixed-term contracts and the dynamics of labor demand," European Economic Review, 45(3), 533-552. Guerrazzi, M. (2011), “Wage bargaining as an optimal control problem: A dynamic version of the right-to-manage model," Optimal Control Applications and Methods, 32(5), 609-622. Hamermesh, D. S. (1995), “Labor Demand and the Source of Adjustment Costs," The Economic Journal, 620-634. Hamermesh, D. S. (1996), Labor Demand, Princeton University Press. Hamermesh, D. S., and Pfann, G. A. (1996), “Adjustment costs in factor demand," Journal of Economic Literature, 1264-1292. Holt, C. C., Modigliani, F., Muth, J. F., and Simon, H. A. (1960), Production Planning, Inventories, and Workforce, Prentice Hall, New York. Jaramillo, F., Schiantarelli, F., and Sembenelli, A. (1993), “Are adjustment costs for labor asymmetric? An econometric test on panel data for Italy," The Review of Economics and Statistics, 640-648. Jones, S. R. (1987), “Union membership and employment dynamics," Economics Letters, 25(2), 197-200. Kazanas, T., and Miaouli, N. (2014), “Wage-setting and capital in unionized markets: Evidence from South Europe," Economic Modelling, 37, 368-376. Kidd, D. P., and Oswald, A. J. (1987), “A dynamic model of trade union behaviour," Economica, 355-365. Koba, T. (2003), “The Period of Labor Adjustment and Bargaining Models," Kobe University Economic Review, 49, 83-98. Lindbeck, A., and Snower, D. J. (2001), “Insiders versus outsiders," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 165-188. Modesto, L., and Thomas, J. P. (2001), “An analysis of labor adjustment costs in unionized economies," Labor Economics, 8(4), 475-501. Nickell, S. J. (1987), “Dynamic models of labor demand," in O. Ashenfelter D. Card (ed.): Handbook of Labor Economics Vol. 1, North Holland, pp. 473-522. Palokangas, T. (1992), “Binding contracts, profit-sharing and the degree of centralization," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 148(2), 260-273. Palokangas, T. (1997), “The centralization of wage bargaining, Investment, and technological change," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 153(4), 657-657. Pfann, G. A., and Palm, F. C. (1993), “Asymmetric adjustment costs in non-linear labor demand models for the Netherlands and UK manufacturing sectors," The Review of Economic Studies, 60(2), 397-412. Van der Ploeg, F. (1987), “Trade unions, investment, and employment: a non-cooperative approach," European Economic Review, 31(7), 1465-1492. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/77562 |