Deb, Joyee and Zhou, Jidong (2018): Reference Dependence and Choice Overload.
Preview |
PDF
MPRA_paper_86261.pdf Download (629kB) | Preview |
Abstract
This paper offers an explanation for choice overload based on reference-dependent preferences. Consumers construct an ideal object that combines the best attributes of all objects in their choice set, and use this as a reference point. When the choice set expands, it is more likely to find a better object, but meanwhile the reference point improves, which makes all existing objects appear worse. We characterize when the latter reference-dependence effect dominates such that choice overload arises. We also show that purchase probability can decrease with object complexity, measured by the number of attributes.
Item Type: | MPRA Paper |
---|---|
Original Title: | Reference Dependence and Choice Overload |
Language: | English |
Keywords: | choice overload, reference dependence, loss aversion |
Subjects: | D - Microeconomics > D1 - Household Behavior and Family Economics > D11 - Consumer Economics: Theory D - Microeconomics > D9 - Intertemporal Choice M - Business Administration and Business Economics ; Marketing ; Accounting ; Personnel Economics > M3 - Marketing and Advertising > M30 - General |
Item ID: | 86261 |
Depositing User: | Jidong Zhou |
Date Deposited: | 18 Apr 2018 10:13 |
Last Modified: | 28 Sep 2019 15:26 |
References: | Abaluck, J., and J. Gruber (2018): “Less is More: Improving Choices by Limiting Choices in Health Insurance Markets,” mimeo. Bachi, B., and R. Spiegler (2018): “Buridanic Competition,” Games and Economic Behavior, 107, 298–315. Bertrand, M., D. Karlan, S. Mullainathan, E. Shafir, and J. Zinman (2010): “What’s Advertising Content Worth? Evidence from a Consumer Credit Marketing Field Experiment,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(1), 263–306. Bordalo, P., N. Gennaioli, and A. Shleifer (2013):“Salience and Consumer Choice,” Journal of Political Economy, 121(5), 803–843. Borovoi, L., N. Liberman, and Y. Trope (2010): “The effects of attractive but unattainable alternatives on the attractiveness of near and distant future menus,” Judgment and Decision Making, 5(2), 102–109. Buturak, G., and O. Evren (2017): “Chocie Overload and Asymmetric Regret,” Theoretical Economics, 12(3), 1029–1056. Chernev, A., U. Bockenholt, and J. Goodman (2015): “Choice Overload: A Conceptual Review and Meta-Analysis,” Journal of Consumer Psychology, 25(2), 333–358. Dhar, R. (1997): “Consumer Preference for a No-Choice Option,” Journal of Consumer Research, 24(2), 215–231. Frick, M. (2016): “Monotone Threshold Representations,” Theoretical Economics, 11(3), 757–772. Fudenberg, D., R. Iijima, and T. Strzalecki (2016): “Stochastic Choice and Revealed Perturbed Utility,” Working paper version. Gerasimou, G. (Forthcoming): “Indecisiveness, Undesirability and Overload Revealed Through Rational Choice Deferral,” Economic Journal. Huber, J., J. W. Payne, and C. Puto (1982): “Adding Asymmetrically Dominated Alternatives: Violations of Regularity and the Similarity Hypothesis,” Journal of Consumer Research, 9(1), 90–98. Iyengar, S. S., G. Huberman, and G.Jiang (2004): “How Much Choice is Too Much? Contributions to 401(k) Retirement Plans,” in Pension Design and Structure: New Lessons from Behavioral Finance, ed. by O. S. Mitchell, and S. P. Utkus. Oxford University Press. Iyengar, S. S., and M. R. Lepper (2000): “When Choice is Demotivating: Can One Desire Too Much of a Good Thing?,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 79(6), 995–1006. Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky (eds.) (2000): Choices, values, and frames. Cambridge University Press. Kamenica, E. (2008): “Contextual Inference in Markets: On the Informational Content of Product Lines,” American Economic Review, 98(5), 2127–2149. Ke, T., Z. Shen, and J. Villas-Boas (2016): “Search for information on multiple products,” Management Science, 62(12), 3576–3603. Kuksov, D., and M. Villas-Boas (2010): “When More Alternatives Lead to Less Choice,” Marketing Science, 29(3), 507–524. Ortoleva, P. (2013): “The Price of Flexibility: Towards A Theory of Thinking Aversion,” Journal of Economic Theory, 148, 903–934. Proschan, F. (1965): “Peakedness of Distributions of Convex Combinations,” Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 36(6), 1703–1706. Ravid, D. (2015): “Focus, Then Compare,” mimeo, University of Chicago. Sagi, A., and N. Friedland (2007): “The Cost of Richness: The Effect of the Size and Diversity of Decision Sets on Post-Decision Regret,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 93(4), 515–524. Sarver, T. (2008): “Anticipating Regret: Why Fewer Options May Be Better,” Econometrica, pp. 263–305. Scheibehenne, B., P. Greifeneder, and P. Todd (2010a): “Can There Ever Be Too Many Options? A Meta-Analytic Review of Choice Overload,” Journal of Consumer Research, 37(3), 409–425. Scheibehenne, B., P. Greifeneder, and P. Todd (2010b): “Less may be more when choosing is difficult: Choice complexity and too much choice,” Acta Psychologica, 133(1), 45 – 50. Schwartz, B. (2004): The Paradix of Choice: Why More is Less. HarperCollins. Simonson, I. (1989): “Choice Based on Reasons: The Case of Attraction and Compromise Effects,” Journal of Consumer Research, 16(2), 158–174. Tversky, A., and E. Shafir (1992): “Choice Under Conflict: The Dynamics of Deferred Decision,” Psychological Science, 4(6), 358–361. Tversky, A., and I. Simonson (1993): “Context-Dependent Preferences,” Management Science, 39(10), 1179–1189. |
URI: | https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/id/eprint/86261 |